TRADE POLICY AND MARKET POWER: FIRM‐LEVEL EVIDENCE

AuthorOlivier Cadot,Alan Asprilla,Nicolas Berman,Mélise Jaud
Published date01 November 2019
Date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12409
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 4, November 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12409
TRADE POLICY AND MARKET POWER: FIRM-LEVEL EVIDENCE
BYALAN ASPRILLA,NICOLAS BERMAN,OLIVIER CADOT,AND M´
ELISE JAUD1
University of Lausanne, Switzerland; Aix-Marseille University, CNRS,EHESS, Centrale
Marseille, AMSE, France, CEPR, UK; University of Lausanne, Switzerland, CEPR, U.K.,and
FERDI, France; World Bank, U.S.A.
This article identifies the effect of trade policy on market power through new data and a new identification
strategy. We identify market power by observing how exporting firms price discriminate across markets following
variations in bilateral exchange rates. Pricing-to-market is prevalent in all countries in our sample, even among
small firms, although it is increasing in firm size. More importantly, we find that the effect of nontariff measures
(NTMs) is not isomorphic to that of tariffs. Whereas tariffs reduce the market power of foreign firms through
rent-shifting effects, NTMs reinforce the market power of nonexiting firms, domestic and foreign alike.
1. INTRODUCTION
Although the argument that trade policy affects competition is an old one (see, e.g., de
Melo and Urata, 1986), there is to date little systematic evidence on how trade policy affects
market power at the level of the firm and, in particular, how the effects of different trade policy
instruments play out. In a heterogeneous firms setting, nontariff measures (NTMs)—a widely
used class of trade policy instruments including, for example, technical or sanitary regulations—
affect market structure in ways that are not isomorphic to tariffs. Instead of merely shifting rents
from foreign to domestic firms, they also change market structure by affecting firms differently
depending on their size. For instance, a regulation may inadvertently create barriers to entry
that generate a dominant position. Evidence of such effects of tariffs and NTMs is scarce,
however, because assessing the market power of firms and how it relates to trade policy requires
estimating indicators such as price–cost margins or market shares in well-identified markets.
Both the identification of these measures and the definition of a market (and its structure) are
problematic, which is why research has so far limited itself to specific sectors, countries, and
trade policy instruments.
Manuscript received February 2017; revised July 2018.
1Olivier Cadot passed away in March 2019. Olivier was a profoundly kind and thoughtful friend and a remarkable
researcher. Working with him has been a privilege and an incredibly joyful adventure. We are grateful to George
Alessandria, three referees, as well Paulo Bastos, Richard Newfarmer, Frederic Robert-Nicoud, and to seminar partic-
ipants at CERDI, Nice Sophia-Antipolis, the Central Bank of Uganda, the World Bank, the ERF Annual Conference,
the ETSG conference, and the University of Lausanne for useful comments and suggestions. Special thanks to Caroline
Freund for detailed advice. Jingjing Xia provided excellent research assistance. An early version of this article was
prepared as a background paper for the World Bank’s “Champions Wanted” regional study and draws on prior re-
search undertaken with support from the International Growth Center. Support from France’s Agence Nationale de la
Recherche under “Investissement d’Avenir” grant ANR-10-LABX-14-01 and from Switzerland’s NCCR under WP6,
as well as from the governments of Norway, Sweden, and the United Kingdom through the Multi-Donor Trust Fund
for Trade and Development are gratefully acknowledged. M´
elise Jaud appreciates financial support from the Swiss
National Science Foundation. The project leading to this publication has received funding from Excellence Initiative
of Aix-Marseille University—A*MIDEX, a French “Investissements d’Avenir” programme and from the French Na-
tional Research Agency Grant ANR-17-EURE-0020. The opinions expressed in this study are those of the authors and
do not necessarily represent the views of the World Bank, its Board of Directors, or the governments that it represents.
Please address correspondence to: M´
elise Jaud, World Bank Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, U.S.A.
Phone: 202-247-8704. E-mail: mjaud@worldbank.org.
1647
C
(2019) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1648 ASPRILLA ET AL.
This article follows a different route and identifies market power and how it is affected by
trade policy using insights from the pricing-to-market (PTM) literature. We rely on a growing
literature that establishes, theoretically and empirically, that the extent of firm-level PTM relates
to firm size, efficiency, and, ultimately, market power.2PTM implies that a firm faced with a
cost shock will adjust its price differentially across destination markets, depending on the price
elasticity of demand it perceives on each of them, which in turn depends on its market power.
However, neither cost shocks nor market shares are observed directly at the firm level.3Our
identification strategy goes around this by relating firm-level export prices (on which we have
data) to bilateral exchange rate shocks.
Consider a firm faced with a series of bilateral exchange rate shocks, one on each of its
destination markets. If it passed through the entirety of each shock onto consumer prices,
its producer price in the home currency would remain the same irrespective of destinations;
there would be no PTM. However, with incomplete pass-through, a fraction of each shock is
absorbed by the firm into its producer price; as a result, the uniqueness of the producer price
breaks down, giving rise instead to a series of differentiated ones by destination. In other words,
the firm prices to market. Like in the case of a symmetric cost shock, the reaction of a firm’s
producer price to an exchange rate shock tells us something about the elasticity of demand it
perceives on its destination market—that is, about its unobserved market power. Specifically,
a firm with strong market power in a given destination (hence a low perceived price elasticity
of demand) will absorb a large fraction of the bilateral exchange rate shock and conversely. As
destination markets vary in terms of their trade policy, we can then infer the effect of trade
policy on market structure by observing the pricing behavior of firms exporting there without
directly needing to observe their market shares or any other measure of market power.
We start by discussing the impact of trade policy instruments on PTM in the destination coun-
try using a class of heterogenous firms models featuring variable and endogenous markups. We
derive two main testable predictions, respectively, related to NTMs and to tariffs. Specifically,
we show that NTMs applied in a nondiscriminatory fashion—that is, in compliance with the
WTO’s “national treatment” clause, whereby imported and domestically produced products
must be treated alike—raise market power and PTM for incumbents if they induce the exit
of smaller firms, for example, through higher fixed costs.4Import tariffs, on the other hand,
decrease the sales of incumbents but also induce the exit of small firms, leading to an ambiguous
impact on market power. However, given their discriminatory nature, tariffs are more likely
to displace foreign firms in favor of domestic ones, implying that the intensive margin effect
dominates and in net tariffs reduce the market shares of exporters and thus their incentive to
engage in PTM.5
We then test these predictions using a large multicountry firm-level data set obtained from
customs administrations in 12 developing countries, ranging from low income to middle income.
We combine the firm-level data with destination product specific data on bilateral applied
tariffs as well as NTMs. The latter covers a wide range of measures ranging from sanitary and
phytosanitary measures to technical barriers to trade. Pooling together firm-level data from
several developing countries allows us to provide evidence on the extent of exchange rate pass-
through for countries and regions that have received little attention so far. It also allows us
to explore more systematically the impact of trade policy on competition and market power
using a sample of countries facing different trade policy arrangements, in particular preferential
tariffs. Importantly, the high dimensionality of the data enables us to account for unobserved
2See, for example, Krugman (1986), Feenstra et al. (1996), Atkeson and Burstein (2008), Berman et al. (2012), Auer
and Schoenle (2016), or Amiti et al. (2014).
3Market shares are not even observed at the more aggregated product level, as domestic firm sales are typically
not observed.
4We will leave aside the case of quantitative restrictions, as those have largely been phased out, and focus on
regulations, either sanitary or technical, of which there is a plethora in high- and middle-income countries.
5In the online appendix, we also provide a detailed discussion of these predictions using a specific model from
Atkeson and Burstein (2008).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT