Trade in intermediate inputs, customs unions, and global free trade

Published date01 May 2019
AuthorDavid Tsirekidze
Date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12392
666
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:666–693.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Article XXIV of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) allows groups of countries to
eliminate tariffs on each other that they do not have to extend to other members of the World Trade
Organization (WTO). These preferential trade agreements (PTAs) might take the form of free trade
agreements (FTAs) or customs unions (CUs). In the first case, member countries are free to choose
their own external tariffs for imports from nonmembers, while in the second case members set jointly
optimal external tariffs leading to coordination benefit.1 In this paper, my emphasis will be on CUs
only where the members of a CU treat nonmembers in a discriminatory manner, and this has an ad-
verse effect on the nonmember country’s welfare.
Received: 24 August 2018
|
Revised: 8 January 2019
|
Accepted: 10 January 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12392
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Trade in intermediate inputs, customs unions, and
global free trade
DavidTsirekidze
Edgeworth Economics, Washington, District
of Columbia
Correspondence
David Tsirekidze, Edgeworth Economics,
1111 19th Street NW, Suite 200, Washington,
DC.
Email: dtsirekidze@edgewortheconomics.
com
Abstract
In a three‐country customs union (CU) formation game, I
introduce international trade in intermediate inputs and
rules of origin (RoO) restrictions. In the case of symmetric
countries, I show that as countries become more involved
in global supply chains, global free trade is less likely to be
a stable equilibrium outcome. RoO can help solve this
problem. In the case of asymmetry, depending on the de-
gree of the globalization, free riding (for high degree) or
exclusion motive (for low degree) prevents global free
trade. Correspondingly, I show that RoO can have helpful
or detrimental effects on attaining global free trade.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F13, F15
|
667
TSIREKIDZE
Since we see that tariffs are declining over time, the importance of nontariff barriers rises.2 The
type of barrier I focus on in this paper is called “rules of origin” (RoO) and it restricts the use of inter-
mediate inputs used in the final goods production traded within the CU. Although one may attribute
RoOs only to FTAs as a way to prevent nonmember countries exploiting differences in tariffs they
face when exporting to FTA member countries, CUs too may impose RoOs in order to ensure imports
maintain a minimum amount of CU member content. For example, in the case of the EU Customs
Union, in order for the office machines (Harmonized System [HS] headings 8456 to 8466) to be traded
duty free within the member countries, all the nonoriginating materials used in the manufacture of the
office machines must not account for more than 40% of the price of the finished product. Similarly,
the EU Customs Union also has RoOs for its imports from countries under the Generalized System of
Preferences (GSP) to ensure that GSP countries only receive preferential treatment when their exports
contain at least a certain amount of GSP content. For example, in the case of umbrellas (HS heading
6601) nonoriginating materials used should not exceed 70% of the price of the product.3
What effect does this have on the creation of CUs and the global trade regime? Does its existence
help achieve global free trade? To investigate these questions, in this paper I consider the interna-
tional trade model with intermediate inputs and RoO restrictions. So, we have three countries, each
producing two goods and consuming all three. Therefore, each country’s import market is served
by two “competing exporters” as in Bagwell and Staiger (1999). Any pair of countries can initiate a
CU, and this determines the global trade regime. A stable equilibrium outcome of this endogenous
CU creation game is global free trade if there are no self‐enforcing deviations (i.e., deviations that
are profitable for deviating countries and neither of these countries want to subsequently deviate
unilaterally).
To understand why there might not be global free trade as an equilibrium outcome of the game,
we need to examine the incentives of countries to deviate from it. There are two major impediments
to global free trade: (1) a country prefers to stay out of the trade agreement of the other two countries;
and (2) a pair of countries prefer to exclude the third country. For the first effect, the RoO can mitigate
this by limiting the benefits that the nonmember country gets. At the same time, the RoO make mem-
ber countries better off, as most of the benefits from trade agreements now go to them, as opposed to
the nonmember country.
However, in contrast to the first case, in the second case all the RoO can do is to make the members
even more willing to exclude the nonmember (and they will be better off by doing so). Therefore,
RoO can only shrink the parameter space under which global free trade is a stable Nash equilibrium
outcome. As I show below, this is true in the case of asymmetric countries. The smaller ones, taking
into account the effect of their tariffs on the other CU member’s welfare, can effectively be better off
by excluding the larger country.
Note that depending on the degree of trade in intermediate inputs the first or the second effect is
operational. When countries are highly interconnected and their inputs are extensively used in the
final goods production abroad, the free riding effect is more important, and we are in the first scenario.
However, when that interconnectedness is weak, we have a typical case of CU members benefiting by
excluding the nonmember from the trade agreement and exploiting the terms of trade gains.
Given the intuition above, the conclusion I make in this paper is that RoO can be helpful in the
CU case when there is a high degree of globalization. However, in the other scenario, where there is a
small degree of trade in intermediate inputs, RoO only makes global free trade harder to achieve as it
incentivizes the smaller countries to exclude the larger country even more.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, I review the closely related literature.
Section 3 introduces the basic model based on Saggi, Woodland, and Yildiz (2013). There, the CU for-
mation game is discussed, and the importance of country asymmetry is highlighted. In Section 4, the

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT