THE IMPACT OF BODY WEIGHT ON OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY AND CAREER DEVELOPMENT

Published date01 May 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12364
Date01 May 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 2, May 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12364
THE IMPACT OF BODY WEIGHT ON OCCUPATIONAL MOBILITY AND CAREER
DEVELOPMENT
BYMATTHEW C. HARRIS1
University of Tennessee, U.S.A.
This article examines the relationship between individuals’ weight and employment decisions over the life
cycle. I estimate a dynamic stochastic model of individuals’ annual choices of occupation, hours worked, and
schooling. Evidence suggests that heavier individuals face higher switching costs when transitioning into white-
collar occupations, earn lower returns to experience in white-collar occupations, and earn lower wages in socially
intensive jobs. I simulate a hypothetical antidiscrimination policy treating obese workers as a protected class.
Although such a policy would reduce gaps in occupational attainment, it would have little effect on the observed
divergence in wages between obese and nonobese workers.
1. INTRODUCTION
How does body weight affect employment behavior and wages over the life cycle? We know
obesity yields high costs in the workplace.2Estimates place annual workplace productivity costs
of obesity between $12 and $30 billion. Although obese workers miss 15%–50% more work
time than healthy weight workers, two-thirds of these productivity costs are due to decreased
at-work performance. Reduced productivity not only affects contemporaneous wages and em-
ployment decisions, but also decreases subsequent pay increases and employment opportunities
(Holmstrom, 1999). Body weight today affects the expected present discounted value of em-
ployment decisions not only by affecting contemporaneous wages and utility but also expected
future wages and labor market opportunities.
The workplace costs of high body weight are inherently dynamic and vary by occupation.
Studies have shown that obesity leads to difficulty managing professional interpersonal rela-
tionships and reduces stamina when performing physical tasks.3Although lower productivity
affects wages, difficulties with certain job requirements may yield additional nonmonetary costs
that also influence occupational choices. An individual’s body weight may also provide a signal
about that individual’s self-discipline or work ethic, the value of which may differ between
occupations. Such a negative signal would lead to decreased occupational mobility for heavier
individuals. Differences between occupations in the expected costs of high body weight pro-
vide additional motivation for modeling these costs as a part of forward-looking individuals’
employment decisions. When an individual chooses an occupation, he accrues human capital
that is not perfectly transferable to other occupations (Kambourov and Manovskii, 2009). Thus,
Manuscript received January 2015; revised May 2018.
1I would like to thank Donna Gilleskie, Brian McManus, David Guilkey, Helen Tauchen, Clement Joubert, Steven
Stern, Maarten Lindeboom, Ahmed Khwaja, William Neilson, Carl Sanders, Chris Cronin, Michael Darden, participants
in the UNC Applied Microeconomics Workshop, Triangle Health Economics Workshop, Annual Health Economics
Conference, and the 6th Biennial Conference of the American Society of Health Economists. I also thank my editor,
Hanming Fang and two anonymous referees for their invaluable comments and stewardship. All errors are mine. Please
address correspondence to: Matthew C. Harris, Department of Economics and Center for Business and Economic
Research, 722 Stokely Management Center, 916 Volunteer Boulevard, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996.
Phone: 865-974-5591. E-mail: mharris@utk.edu.
2See, for example, Ricci and Chee (2005) and Andryeva (2014).
3See Pronk et al. (2004), Johar and Katayama (2012), Hamermesh and Biddle (1994), DeBeaumont (2009), and Han
et al. (2009).
631
C
(2018) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
632 HARRIS
contemporaneous occupational choice affects both expected future wages and future occupa-
tional decisions. Finally, an individual’s body weight is itself dynamic and maybe affected by
one’s choice of occupation and hours.
Despite the inherent dynamic relationship between body weight and employment outcomes,
the existing literature on the subject has largely relied on static approaches and abstracted from
either occupational choice or wages. I formulate and estimate a dynamic discrete choice model
where body weight affects both the distribution of wage offers and nonmonetary costs of each
employment alternative, and employment decisions subsequently affect weight. Although the
model therefore treats body weight as endogenous, it does so in a limited sense. Individuals
do not choose body weight per se, but their body weight evolves as a consequence of the
individuals’ history of employment decisions.4Both the model and empirics follow in the
occupational choice tradition of Keane and Wolpin (1997), Lee (2005), Lee and Wolpin (2006),
Kambourov and Manovskii (2009), Sullivan (2010), and Baird (2014). I construct indices of
the intensity of mental, physical, and social job requirements for each occupation to examine
how job requirements affect the wage and nonmonetary costs of body weight. I estimate the
parameters governing the individual’s decision-making process using data from the National
Longitudinal Survey of Youth, 1979 cohort.
This is the first article to examine differences in earnings and occupational attainment on the
basis of body weight in a dynamic discrete occupational choice framework. Dynamic stochastic
occupational choice models have been utilized to examine gender gaps in wages and occupa-
tional attainment (e.g., Altug and Miller, 1998; Flabbi, 2010; Eckstein and Lifshitz, 2011; Gayle
and Golan, 2012; Yamaguchi, 2013) and similar black–white gaps (e.g., Keane and Wolpin,
2000; Bowlus and Eckstein, 2002; Lehmann, 2013). However, much of the existing literature on
the relationship between body weight and employment outcomes has used static methods and
examined contemporaneous cross-occupation “wage penalties” for body weight (e.g., Pagan
and Davila, 1997; Cawley, 2004; Han et al., 2009; Johar and Katayama, 2012).5When occupa-
tion has been considered, it is usually as a control variable or mediating factor in the associative
relationship between weight and mean wages. To the extent that body weight increases fric-
tion when transitioning into certain occupations, treating occupation as a control excludes an
important mechanism by which body weight can affect wages.
This article also contributes to a growing literature where job requirements are incorporated
into dynamic models as a determinant of occupational choice (Sanders, 2010; Yamaguchi, 2012)
and the literature on how one’s employment behavior affects one’s health (e.g., King et al.,
2001; Lakdawalla and Philipson, 2002; Courtemanche, 2009; Kelly et al., 2014, Ravesteijn et al.,
2014). Additionally, this article incorporates prospective wage differentials into a single-agent
occupational choice framework. As Coate and Loury (1993) show, anticipated wage differentials
can affect the formation of human capital, which affects subsequent wages. Theoretically, the
model seeks to merge Mincer (1958), Ben-Porath (1967), and Becker (1957). The structure of
this model closely resembles Keane and Wolpin (1997) and Sullivan (2010), focusing on how
current and expected future monetary and nonmonetary costs affect individuals’ decisions over
the life cycle. There is also a small methodological contribution to the literature on dynamic
models of occupational choice regarding the distribution of unobserved wages. I estimate the
full distribution of wages inside the model using conditional density estimation (CDE; Gilleskie
and Mroz, 2004) instead of imposing a parametric distribution on wages. Additionally, CDE
allows the marginal effect of explanatory variables to vary over the support of the dependent
variable. This feature is useful given that Kline and Tobias (2008) and Johar and Katayama
4The purpose of this article is not to investigate the effects of employment decisions on weight, but rather the
opposite. The model permits employment decisions to affect body weight, but through a feedback mechanism instead
of modeling change in body weight as a choice.
5Notable exceptions to the lack of dynamic modeling include Gilleskie et al. (2011) and Tosini (2008), but neither
study models occupational choice.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT