STRATEGIC BIDDING AND CONTRACT RENEGOTIATION

Published date01 May 2019
AuthorHojin Jung,Carlos Lamarche,Richard Sicotte,Georgia Kosmopoulou
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12368
Date01 May 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 2, May 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12368
STRATEGIC BIDDING AND CONTRACT RENEGOTIATION
BYHOJIN JUNG,GEORGIA KOSMOPOULOU,CARLOS LAMARCHE,AND RICHARD SICOTTE1
Chonbuk National University, Korea; University of Oklahoma, U.S.A.; University of Kentucky,
U.S.A.; University of Vermont,U.S.A.
When firms bid in procurement auctions, they take into account the likelihood of future contract renegotia-
tions. If they anticipate that certain input quantities will change ex post, they have an incentive to strategically
skew their itemized bids, thereby increasing profits for themselves and costs for the procuring agency. We
develop and estimate a structural model of strategic bidding using a data set of road construction projects in
Vermont. We find that bidding strategies lead to increased markups for renegotiated items and reduced markups
for nonrenegotiated items, results consistent with bid-skewing.
1. INTRODUCTION
Most, if not all, procurement contracts are later renegotiated. These renegotiations are often
precipitated by engineers determining, after the contract is awarded, that the actual require-
ments of the project differ from what was originally anticipated. In many contexts, the rules for
amending the contract ex post are carefully delineated. For example, the U.S. government’s
procurement regulations prohibit changing contractually agreed prices unless an item is added
in the field or there is a relevant price adjustment clause (Kosmopoulou and Zhou, 2014; Kos-
mopoulou et al., 2016). However, adjustments to the quantities of labor and materials are not
only permitted but are commonplace.
Procuring agencies and contractors reasonably expect—are even certain—that renegotiations
will ensue, but they are not certain of the precise nature of the changes. Moreover, it is widely
acknowledged that firms modify their bidding strategies based upon their own expectations of
subsequent alterations to the contract. These perceptions by industry participants are backed
by past scholarly work. For example, Athey and Levin (2001) found that forward-looking firms
skew their bids in U.S. Forest Service timber auctions by submitting high (low) unit prices on
types of timber in anticipation that their actual proportion will decrease (increase) from original
Forest Service estimates. Bajari et al. (2014), in their study of the California highway construc-
tion industry, argue that renegotiations are costly for firms, because they need to alter previous
plans and reallocate firm resources. They estimate that when contract quantities are changed
ex post, firms bear adaptation costs of $2.20 for each dollar of additional work. Accordingly,
firms bid less aggressively on projects in which they anticipate contract renegotiations. Our
study examines how the prospect of ex post renegotiation in road construction projects in Ver-
mont affects contractors’ bids and profits. We investigate bid-skewing, a situation when a firm
Manuscript received October 2016; revised July 2018.
1The authors would like to thank Javier Donna, seminar participants at the Athens University of Economics
and Business, Colorado School of Mines, Northeastern University, University of California Merced, University of
Virginia, Vanderbilt University, Virginia Tech, and the University of Piraeus, and conference participants at the
2013 International Industrial Organization Conference, the 2013 Conference on Research on Economic Theory and
Econometrics, and the 2014 Workshop on Public Procurement and Concession Design for comments related to this
work.We are indebtedto staff at the Vermont Agency of Transportation (VTrans) for providing useful information. This
research has been supported by VTrans Grant No. SPR722. Please address correspondence to: Georgia Kosmopoulou,
Department of Economics, University of Oklahoma, 308 Cate Center Drive, CCD1, Norman, OK 73019. E-mail:
georgiak@ou.edu.
801
C
(2018) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
802 JUNG ET AL.
anticipates a positive quantity adjustment in one item and strategically bids higher on that item
while decreasing its bid on other items in order to maintain a competitive aggregate bid. We
find strong evidence that firms engage in strategic bid-skewing, raising profit margins.
Our article differs from existing work in two important ways. First, we adapt the analysis
of contract renegotiations of Bajari et al. (2014) to itemized bid-level data, which allows us
to investigate skewed bidding as in Athey and Levin (2001). A thorough exploration of bid-
manipulation in complex contracts requires careful examination of item-level bids. The analysis
of bid aggregates at the project level, while informative, does not reveal the extent to which firms
strategically manipulate their bids. We employ itemized bid information to construct estimates
of the markup of bids above costs, and we compare how they vary across items with and without
positive quantity renegotiation. The variation in markups across items provides evidence on
how firms’ anticipation of change orders affects their bidding behavior. Second, we conduct
this work on a new data set of all construction projects undertaken by the Vermont Agency of
Transportation (VTrans) over a five-year period. One of the novel features of these data is that
they include firm-level financial information, normally not available because of their proprietary
character. Another novelty is that it permits us to control for price adjustment clauses, which
have been omitted in previous studies.
In the next section, we explain the renegotiation, or “change order” process for VTrans con-
struction contracts. We introduce our data and conduct a reduced-form analysis that illustrates
the sensitivity of standard bid regressions to different types of contract revisions. We also de-
velop a structural model of strategic itemized bidding where firms expect adjustments to the
quantities of work and materials in the contract, and we estimate costs and markups, exploring
patterns of bid-skewing at the item level. A study of the size of adjustments due to renegotiation
at the project level can be used to assess the overall impact of uncertainty and firm heterogeneity
on markups, but the test may confound such effects with influences from a number of sources,
including adaptation costs. We circumvent this problem by focusing our analysis on a subsample
of projects that have a similar set of tasks and whose characteristics closely fit the Independent
Private Value (IPV) model. We use nonparametric estimation methods similar to the ones
developed by Guerre et al. (2000) and Bajari et al. (2014) to estimate the distribution of latent
costs after controlling for project heterogeneity.
We first present reduced-form evidence of strategic behavior, including results that show bid-
skewing within projects. The structural analysis reveals that unit costs and markups are increased
among items that were renegotiated after a project was awarded. Our results also show that
while bidders increase their markups on items that have positive quantity adjustments by 10%–
17% at the median level, they lower their bids and markups on items that are not renegotiated
to maximize their potential surplus ex post while maintaining the likelihood to win at a high
level. The behavior leads to a significant increase in the cost of contracting to the state and the
public, higher than that reported by studies considering all forms of renegotiation.
2. DATA AND REDUCED-FORM ESTIMATES
2.1. Overview of Change Orders on VermontTransportation Contracts. Our data set consists
of the complete bidding and payment records of all construction projects auctioned off between
May 2004 and December 2009 by the VTrans. There are 846 bids on 312 individual projects. At
the item level, there are 50,465 bids on 712 items. We classify auctions by project type: asphalt
projects, bridge projects, and miscellaneous projects.2The agency awards contracts to the lowest
bidders in sealed bid auctions held monthly. When advertising a project to the public, VTrans
provides detailed engineer’s plans and information on the work site, the required completion
date, and a brief description of the project.3The engineer’s plans provide a list of quantities for
2Miscellaneous projects include traffic signaling and lighting, grading and draining, parking lots, and landscaping.
3Prequalification status is achieved by the successful completion of two procedures: (i) annual prequalification: the
prequalification committee at VTrans annually assigns each firm certain limitations as to the value of projects and

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT