SIZE, OPENNESS, AND MACROECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12208
Date01 February 2017
AuthorRoland Straub,Alexander Chudik
Published date01 February 2017
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 1, February 2017
SIZE, OPENNESS, AND MACROECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
BYALEXANDER CHUDIK AND ROLAND STRAUB1
Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas,U.S.A; European Central Bank, Germany
One common, simplifying assumption in open economy macroliterature is that the rest of the world can be thought of
as a representative economy. This article formally investigates conditions under which this assumption can be justified
using a multicountry general equilibrium model as a laboratory. We derive the conditions that ensure the existence
of the equilibrium and study the properties of the equilibrium using large Nasymptotics. Thereby, we show that the
two-country framework is a valid approximation only for economies that have diversified trade linkages and only when
there is no globally dominant economy among the foreign economies.
1. INTRODUCTION
What determines the impact of foreign shocks on the domestic business cycle? What are the
features that drive macroeconomic interdependence? These questions remain of high impor-
tance in an increasingly open and globalized world. The analysis of macroeconomic interdepen-
dence, however, has been so far constrained in several dimensions in both the empirical and the
theoretical literature.
In the empirical literature, the difficulty of analyzing macroeconomic interdependence starts
by recognizing the “curse of dimensionality” that is associated with estimating an unrestricted
system featuring a relatively large number of endogenous macroeconomic variables.2There
are two main approaches to mitigate the so-called curse of dimensionality in the literature:
(i) shrinkage of the parameter space and (ii) shrinkage of data. Bayesian estimation, which
circumvents the dimensionality problem via imposition of priors on the parameters of the
model, is an example of shrinkage of the parameter space.3A much more common practice is to
deal with the high dimensionality problem in the open economy macroeconomic literature using
the second approach, shrinkage of data. Under this approach, the rest of the world is typically
approximated with one representative economy, which is constructed as the cross-sectional
(trade-) weighted average of foreign economies.4In the theoretical literature, variables of the
representative foreign economy can be treated either as endogenous or as exogenous with
respect to the variables of the home economy. The latter case is usually labeled as the so-called
Manuscript received December 2012; revised July 2015.
1Earlier version of the article was circulated under the title: “Equilibrium of a Large Multicountry DSGE Model.”
We are greatly indebted to Hashem Pesaran for his support and many useful discussions. We are grateful to the editor
and the anonymous referees for valuable comments. We would also like to thank Seppo Honkapohja and Rupert Gatti
for their guidance during the earlier stages of this research and Kevin Sheedy and Dennis Novy for comments and
helpful discussions. All errors are our responsibility. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors and
do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas or the European Central Bank. Please address
correspondence to: Alexander Chudik, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, 2200 N. Pearl Street, Dallas, TX 75201. E-mail:
alexander.chudik@dal.frb.org.
2Even with as few as four macroeconomic variables per country, it is not possible to reliably estimate an unrestricted
VAR featuring more than two economies due to the size of typical macroeconomic data sets.
3See, for example, Canova and Ciccarelli (2004) or Canova and Ciccarelli (2009) for Bayesian multicountry VAR
models with an application to G7 economies. Priors could be derived from a theoretical model, as discussed in Del
Negro and Schorfheide (2004).
4This approach is prevalent in both theoretical and applied work, including the recent Global VAR (GVAR)
literature started by Pesaran et al. (2004).
33
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
34 CHUDIK AND STRAUB
small-open economy framework.5In such a framework, a rise in trade openness is generally
associated with an increase in macroeconomic interdependence.
But under what conditions is the assumption of a representative foreign economy justified?
And what is the relationship between openness, the size of the economy, and the degree
of macroeconomic interdependence in an alternative framework that addresses some of the
deficiencies of the two-country models?
In this article, we answer these questions by examining the properties of the equilibrium of an
N-country open economy model. Our theoretical setup draws on recent contributions of open
economy general equilibrium models as discussed in Benigno and Benigno (2003), Chari et al.
(2002), Corsetti and Pesenti (2001), Gali and Monacelli (2005), Kollmann (2001), and Schmitt-
Grohe and Uribe (2003) to mention just a few. First, we show the existence of a well-defined
equilibrium in our N-country model and derive the conditions that characterize the equilibrium.
Second, we apply large Nasymptotics to simplify the equilibrium solution of the model.
Indeed, large Nasymptotics, which are commonly used in the panel data literature but
rarely in theoretical macroliterature, turn out to be very useful and necessary in simplifying the
complex equilibrium solution, even under a general pattern of weak cross-sectional dependence
of all idiosyncratic shocks to individual economies.6In particular, large Nasymptotics allow us to
formally define various concepts such as that of “negligible impact,” the notion of neighborhood
effects and global dominance, and to establish order of magnitude restrictions on the coefficients
of the model, which, in turn, significantly simplify the equilibrium solution (as N→∞).7As
a result, large Nasymptotics allow us to study how restrictions on the parameters of the
model (namely, those defining steady-state bilateral foreign trade share matrix) affect the
equilibrium solution and to assess, thereby, the properties of the dynamic equilibrium under
various scenarios about the size and openness of individual economies.
Interestingly, the analysis of the representative foreign economy assumption provides new
insights into the relationship between macroeconomic interdependence and openness. The
results presented in this article indicate that the degree of macroeconomic interdependence
is not necessarily connected to the notion of trade openness as usually contemplated. In fact,
an increase in openness could well lead to a decreased dependence of the home economy
on foreign shocks. Furthermore, the assumption that an economy is small and open does not
justify approximating the rest of the world with one representative economy, constructed by
a cross-sectional (trade-)weighted average of the rest of the world, or justify the asymptotic
exogeneity of foreign variables. Our findings suggest that the degree of trade diversification is
a key parameter in the chosen setup.
We identify an intuitive analogy with the asset market literature (Chamberlain, 1983; Cham-
berlain and Rothschild, 1983) and the literature on large cross-sectional aggregation (Granger,
1987; Forni and Lippi, 1997). It is well known that only systemic risk has a bearing on effectively
diversified portfolios. In a similar spirit, only those components with strong cross-sectional
dependence (common factors) survive aggregation. Similar reasoning applies here. If a coun-
try diversifies its foreign trade and there is no globally dominant economy among the foreign
economies, then (asymptotically as N→∞) the representative foreign economy assumption
is justified. In this setup, the equilibrium solution for domestic endogenous variables does
5Note that the small-open economy framework is subject to two crucial assumptions; (i) the economy is small and
has no impact on the rest of the world and (ii) the rest of the world can be aggregated into a representative economy.
In our article, we focus on the implication of the second assumption (regardless of the size of economy) and identify
under which conditions the aggregation of foreign economies is justified.
6The concept of weak and strong cross-sectional dependence, formally defined in Chudik et al. (2011), will be
applied to the multicountry open economy model. See also Bailey et al. (2016) for further discussion of cross-section
dependence.
7Restrictions that bind only in the limit as the number of variables approaches infinity are also used in Chudik and
Pesaran (2011), who consider econometric analysis of infinite-dimensional VAR models. This article utilizes limiting
restrictions on the bilateral foreign trade flows and studies the equilibrium properties as the number of countries
becomes large.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT