QUANTIFYING THE IMPACTS OF LIMITED SUPPLY: THE CASE OF NURSING HOMES

Published date01 November 2015
AuthorFumiko Hayashi,Hui Wang,Andrew T. Ching
Date01 November 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12138
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 56, No. 4, November 2015
QUANTIFYING THE IMPACTS OF LIMITED SUPPLY:
THECASEOFNURSINGHOMES
BYANDREW T. CHING,FUMIKO HAYASHI,AND HUI WANG 1
University of Toronto, Canada; Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, U.S.A.; Peking University,
P.R. China
This article develops a new estimation method that accounts for excess demand and the unobserved component
of product quality. We apply our method to study the Wisconsin nursing home market in 1999 and find that nearly
20% of elderly qualified for Medicaid were rationed out. However, our counterfactual experiment shows that the net
welfare gain of fulfilling all nursing home demands may be small, because the welfare gain could be largely offset by the
increase in Medicaid expenditures. We also find that a 1% increase in quality would crowd out 3.2% Medicaid patients
in binding nursing homes.
1. INTRODUCTION
Products or services with limited supply are prevalent in our economy. Examples include
hotels, schools, public housing, hospitals, nursing homes, etc. Due to the stickiness of prices
or government regulations, these services commonly experience excess demand from time to
time. When demand exceeds supply, consumers would either need to wait in line or choose
their second best options. This poses a challenge to researchers who are interested in re-
covering consumer preferences from market shares/sales data available to them—in general,
one cannot use such data alone to infer true underlying consumer preferences. In particu-
lar, without properly taking the extent of rationing into account, the preference parameters
and product quality obtained from the standard estimation procedure could be very mislead-
ing. In this article, we develop an estimation strategy that accounts for excess demand and
the unobserved component of product quality. Our methodology is motivated by the institu-
tional details of the nursing home market. It allows us to quantify the extent of rationing,
price, and quality elasticities of demand and shed light on the potential welfare gain/loss
if we try to fulfill all rationed demand. We apply our framework to study the Wisconsin
nursing home market in 1999, which has been thought to face two main problems: limited
Manuscript received December 2012; revised March 2014.
1We are very grateful to Gautam Gowrisankaran and Tom Holmes for their advice in the early stages of the project.
We thank Holger Sieg (the editor) and two anonymous referees for providing many constructive comments. We also
thank Ig Horstmann, Juanjuan Meng, Kanishka Misra, Matt Mitchell, Judith Mortimer, Ed Norton, John Nyman,
Andrew Sweeting, participants at the AEA annual meeting, Annual Health Econometrics Workshop, CKGSB Mar-
keting Conference, Cowles Foundation Structural Microeconomics Conference, International Industrial Organization
Conference, SICS, FTC Microeconomics Conference and seminar participants at UCLA, UC-Davis, U of Toronto,
John Hopkins University, U of Texas-Dallas, U of Texas-Arlington, U of Guelph, CUHK, NUS, Indiana U, and Carl-
son School of Management for their helpful comments. The views expressed in this article are those of the authors
and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City or the Federal Reserve System.
We acknowledge the financial support provided by the Michael Lee-Chin Family Institute for Corporate Citizenship
at the Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto. Please address correspondence to: Andrew T. Ching,
Rotman School of Management and Department of Economics, University of Toronto, Toronto, ON M5S 2J7, Canada.
Phone: 1-416-946-0728. Fax: 1-416-978-5433. E-mail: aching@rotman.utoronto.ca.
1291
C
(2015) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1292 CHING,HAYASHI,AND WANG
access/rationing and low quality (e.g., Gruenberg and Willemain, 1982; Norton, 1992; Ettner,
1993).2
Besides being a market that commonly experiences excess demand, the nursing home mar-
ket is important on its own because of the substantial growth of the elderly population. To
control for the expenditures on nursing home care, most state governments regulate the in-
dustry in two important ways. First, many state governments restrict supply so that a cer-
tificate of need (CON) is necessary for new nursing homes to enter the market or even
for existing ones to increase their number of beds. Second, state governments regulate the
price that they pay for a large percentage of nursing home care through Medicaid programs.
These regulations have led to two groups of studies.3One group of studies focused on the
effect of Medicaid reimbursement, such as how the level of Medicaid reimbursement rates
affects nursing home quality of care and whether the difference in reimbursement method—
prospective or cost-based payment—affects nursing home outcomes (e.g., Nyman, 1985, 1988a,
1994; Gertler, 1989, 1992; Cohen and Spector, 1996; Grabowski, 2001). Another group of stud-
ies investigated the effects of the CON laws. Because the CON laws can potentially create
excess demand in the market and allow existing nursing homes to establish and preserve mar-
ket power, some of the studies have aimed at examining the empirical relationship between
excess demand/market concentration and market outcomes (e.g., Lee et al., 1983; Nyman,
1988a, 1988b, 1994; Gertler, 1989, 1992; Cohen and Spector, 1996; Spector et al., 1998). Ex-
tending Scanlon’s (1980) pioneering work, studies that used data in the 1970s and early 1980s
found evidence of excess demand (e.g., Nyman, 1985, 1988a, 1988b, 1989, 1994; Gertler, 1989,
1992). Studies that used more recent data, however, suggest that excess demand may become
less prevalent (e.g., Cohen and Spector, 1996; Grabowski, 2001; Grabowski and Angelelli,
2004).
We have learned much from previous work; however, due to the reduced-form modeling
approach, there remain some important questions that this work cannot answer. In general, there
are three limitations. First, many previous studies used market tightness as a proxy for excess
demand. However, a tight market does not always imply that the market has excess demand;
rather, it could be consistent with nursing homes being nearly fully occupied at equilibrium.
More importantly, their approach cannot quantify the extent of rationing because it does not
measure the number of patients who prefer to live in a particular nursing home but which they
cannot enter. Second, when measuring quality provided by a nursing home, most of the previous
studies used either input-based or outcome-based methods, which did not take into account
factors that are unobserved to the econometrician (e.g., reputation). Unobserved factors are
potentially important. They may adjust between the actual quality the nursing home provides
and the average quality that can be produced with the staffing intensity used by the nursing
home. Unobserved factors can also lead to an endogeneity problem of price if one ignores their
presence in estimation. Third, as is well known, the reduced-form approach cannot measure
patient welfare under counterfactual experiments.
In light of these shortcomings in the previous literature, the goal of this article is to develop
a structural demand model and a new estimation strategy that enables us to account for excess
demand and the unobserved component of nursing home quality. After obtaining the structural
parameters of the model, we can quantify the extent of rationing and the potential welfare
gain/loss if we try to fulfill all the rationed demand at prevailing private-pay prices, Medicaid
reimbursement rates, and nursing homes qualities. Motivated by several institutional features
of the nursing home industry, our model assumes that (i) some nursing homes may face excess
2See the report to Congress made by the Health Care Financing Administration in July 2000 (Health Care Financing
Administration, 2000). It is also worth pointing out that a nursing home shortage is a public concern even today. See
“The coming nursing home shortage,” the Fiscal Times (2012) http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/Articles/2012/01/26/The-
Coming-Nursing-Home-Shortage, accessed on Feb 17, 2014.
3Norton (2000) provides an excellent survey on this topic.
IMPACTS OF LIMITED SUPPLY 1293
demand from Medicaid patients; (ii) nursing homes are free to admit private-pay patients first,
who typically pay more than the Medicaid reimbursement rate; (iii) the potential number of
private-pay patients is not large enough for them to face the capacity constraints problem; and
(iv) both private-pay and Medicaid patients rank nursing home quality similarly. The key idea
of our identification strategy is that we need to observe the demand by one group of patients
who do not face the rationing problem (in this case, the private-pay patients), and hence we
can use the revealed preference argument to recover the quality of nursing homes based on
their observed demand. By further assuming that both Medicaid and private-pay patients share
similar preferences for nursing home quality (i.e., the nursing homes’ qualities recovered from
private-pay patients’ demand also apply to Medicaid patients), we can then use our model to
infer the true demand for each nursing home and measure the extent of rationing. Our modeling
assumptions, together with our data set, allow us to extend the estimation approach developed
by Berry (1994), Berry et al. (1995), and Petrin (2002) to obtain the structural parameters of
the model, when we only have access to market share data. Taking this approach allows us
to measure quality of care from patient demand by constructing a “quality index,” which can
potentially lessen the problem of input-based or outcome-based quality measure and address
the endogeneity problem of private-pay prices.4
To estimate our model, we use the 1999 Wisconsin Annual Survey of Nursing Homes, which
contains each nursing home’s characteristics and some statistics of its patients. We also supple-
ment it with the Special Tabulation on Aging from the 2000 Census and the 1999 Wisconsin
Health Survey. We study the nursing home market in 1999 because excess demand for nurs-
ing homes was believed to be common back then, but the limitations of previous empirical
methods were not able to quantify the extent of rationing. Therefore, this environment should
serve as a useful place to illustrate our proposed empirical framework for investigating excess
demand.
Our estimation results suggest that excess demand was still prevalent in Wisconsin in the
late ‘90s. Approximately half of the nursing homes used for this study are estimated to face
binding capacity constraints; about 20% of potential patients who qualified for Medicaid are
rationed out for nursing home care (i.e., they would have chosen to enter nursing homes
if the capacity constraints did not exist); and about 26% of the Medicaid nursing home
patients could not enter their first-choice nursing homes. However, we also find evidence that
the net social welfare gain of removing the capacity constraints may be small, because it is
expensive for the state government to cover additional nursing home care. Our estimation
results show that the unobserved component of quality accounts for 40% of the quality index
and plays an important role in explaining market shares. Moreover, our estimated quality
index suggests that nursing homes tend to provide lower quality of care in counties with tight
supply. Interestingly, it also implies that not-for-profit nursing homes tend to provide better
quality than for-profit nursing homes, which is consistent with what the health service literature
finds.
The rest of the article is organized as follows. Section 2 summarizes some important nursing
home regulations in Wisconsin. Section 3 presents the demand model. Section 4 details the
data, and Section 5 presents the estimation procedure. Estimation results, their implications,
and limitations are provided in Section 6. Finally, Section 7 concludes.
4Unlike our approach, Geyer and Sieg (2013) make use of individual level data on exit rate and an equilibrium model
to infer the unobserved waiting list in public housing. Our article is also closely related to Conlon and Mortimer (2013),
who propose an estimation approach that applies to a situation where all types of consumers could face stock-out
problems. However, their approach is computationally very challenging to implement when there are many products
experiencing stock-out, because it needs to integrate out all possible unobserved orders of stock-out to obtain the
likelihood. Our proposed approach completely avoids this computational problem, given the crucial assumptions we
made. Our article is also related to the marketing literature that focuses on the out-of-stock situation: Bruno and
Vilcassim (2008), Che et al. (2012), Musalem et al. (2010). These papers rely on using proxies to indicate which products
experience out-of-stock.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT