PRODUCTION FUNCTION ESTIMATION WITH UNOBSERVED INPUT PRICE DISPERSION

Date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12172
Published date01 May 2016
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 2, May 2016
PRODUCTION FUNCTION ESTIMATION WITH UNOBSERVED INPUT PRICE
DISPERSION
BYPAUL L. E. GRIECO,SHENGYU LI,AND HONGSONG ZHANG1
The Pennsylvania State University, U.S.A.; Durham University Business School, U.K.; The
University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong
We propose a method to consistently estimate production functions in the presence of input price dispersion when
intermediate input quantities are not observed. We find that the traditional approach to dealing with unobserved
input quantities—using deflated expenditure as a proxy—substantially biases the production estimates. In contrast, our
method controls for heterogeneous input prices by exploiting the first-order conditions of the firm’s profit maximization
problem and consistently recovers the production function parameters. Using our preferred method, we provide
empirical evidence of significant input price dispersion and even wider productivity dispersion than is estimated using
proxy methods.
1. INTRODUCTION
In applications of production function estimation, many data sets do not contain a specific
accounting of intermediate input prices and quantities, but instead only provide information
on the total expenditure on intermediate inputs (i.e., materials). This presents a challenge for
consistent estimation when input prices are not homogeneous across firms or when different
firms have access to different types of inputs (e.g., parts of varying quality). To address this issue,
many previous studies assume a homogenous intermediate input is purchased from a single,
perfectly competitive market. This assumption facilitates the use of input expenditures as a proxy
for quantities (e.g., Levinsohn and Petrin, 2003). However, if this assumption does not hold—for
example, if transport costs create price heterogeneity across geography—then the traditional
proxy-based estimator is inconsistent. The logic of the inconsistency is straightforward: firms will
respond to price differences both by substituting across inputs and adjusting their total output,
causing an endogeneity problem that cannot be controlled for using a Hicks-neutral structural
error term. Even in a narrowly defined industry, perfect competition in input markets is not
likely to hold, so the proxy approach is clearly not ideal. Fortunately, observed variation in labor
input quantities, together with labor and materials expenditures, contains useful information on
the intermediate input price variation across firms. By utilizing this variation within a structural
model of firms’ profit-maximization decisions, we introduce a method to consistently estimate
firms’ production function in the presence of unobserved intermediate input price heterogeneity.
The omitted price problem for production function estimation was first recognized by
Marschak and Andrews (1944). They proposed the use of expenditures and revenues as proxies
for input and output quantities under the assumption that prices were homogeneous across
Manuscript received May 2013; revised January 2015.
1The authors would like to thank participants at the 22nd Annual Meeting of the Midwest Econometrics Group, the
11th Annual International Industrial Organization Conference, the 2013 North American Meetings of the Econometric
Society, and the 2013 Conference of the European Association for Research in Industrial Economics for very helpful
comments. In addition, we benefited from thoughtful comments provided by Andr´
es Aradillas-L ´
opez, Robert Porter,
Joris Pinkse, Mark Roberts, David Rivers, James Tybout, the editor, and two anonymous referees. We are also grateful
to Mark Roberts and James Tybout for providing the data used in the empirical application. All errors are the authors’
own responsibility. Please address correspondence to: Paul L. E. Grieco, Department of Economics, The Pennsylvania
State University, 509 Kern Building, University Park, PA 16802. Phone: 814 867 3310. Fax: 814 863 4775. E-mail:
paul.grieco@psu.edu.
665
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
666 GRIECO,LI,AND ZHANG
firms. In practice, the literature has documented significant dispersions in both input and output
prices across firms and over time (Dunne and Roberts, 1992; Roberts and Supina, 1996, 2000;
Beaulieu and Mattey, 1999; Bils and Klenow, 2004; Ornaghi, 2006; Foster et al., 2008; Kugler
and Verhoogen, 2012). Klette and Griliches (1996) show that the consequence of ignoring the
output price dispersion is a downward bias in the scale estimate of production function.2The ef-
fect of input price dispersion is similar. Using a unique data set containing both inputs price and
quantity data, Ornaghi (2006) documents input price bias under the Cobb–Douglas production
function.
A typical data set for production function estimation contains firm-level revenue, intermediate
(i.e., material) expenditure, total wage expenditure, capital stock, investment, and additional
wage rate/labor quantity. However, quantities and prices for intermediate inputs are often not
available. The basic idea of our approach is to exploit the first-order conditions of firms’ profit
maximization to recover the unobserved physical quantities of inputs from their expenditures.3
We then use this recovered physical quantity of intermediate inputs to consistently estimate the
model parameters. We illustrate our approach using the constant elasticity of substitution (CES)
production function as our leading example. We then briefly discuss how the technique can be
applied to more general production function specifications and incorporate the possibility that
materials expenditure represents the aggregation of a vector of different intermediate inputs.
These extensions are fully developed in the supplemental material.
Our model allows firms to be heterogenous in two unobserved dimensions: They have dif-
ferent total factor productivity and face different intermediate inputs prices. We are able to
recover the joint distribution of unobserved heterogeneity and find that both productivity and
input prices are important sources of heterogeneity across firms. Accounting for input price
heterogeneity can give rise to richer explanations of firm policies. For example, if input prices
are persistent, firms’ exit decisions should be modeled as a cutoff in productivity levels and
input prices, implying that relatively less productive firms may remain in the market when they
have access to lower input prices.
The idea of exploiting the first-order conditions of profit maximization has been employed
in many other studies. Assuming homogeneous input prices, Gandhi et al. (2013) use the trans-
formed first-order conditions of the firm’s profit maximization problem to estimate the elasticity
of substitution and separate the nonstructural errors as the first step in their production function
estimation procedure. Doraszelski and Jaumandreu (2013), also assuming labor and materials
quantities are observed, use the first-order conditions of labor and material choices to recover
the unobserved productivity. Together with a Markov assumption on productivity evolution,
this identifies the production function parameters. Katayama et al. (2009) use the first-order
conditions for profit maximization to construct a welfare-based firm performance measure—an
alternative to traditional productivity measures—based on Bertrand–Nash equilibrium. Epple
et al. (2010) develop a procedure using the first-order condition of the indirect profit function to
estimate the housing supply function. Zhang (2014) uses first-order conditions as constraints to
directly control for structural errors to estimate a production function with nonneutral technol-
ogy shocks in Chinese manufacturing industries. De Loecker (2011), De Loecker and Warzynski
(2012), and De Loecker et al. (2012) also use the first-order condition of labor choice and/or
material choice of profit maximization to estimate firm-level markup. The recovered markup is
then used to analyze firm performance in international trade. Santos (2012) uses the first-order
2Klette and Griliches (1996) provide a structural approach for controlling for output price variation; we incorporate
their approach into our model, which additionally controls for input price variation. Of course, because we assume
profit maximization, it is important that our model include a demand function so that we can derive the firm’s first-order
conditions.
3To be precise, we recover a quality-adjusted index for the physical quantity of materials used by the firm. The
associated materials price also represents a quality-adjusted price. In Section 2.2.2 we extend the model to consider the
case where the firm chooses from several unobserved intermediate input types. Our procedure follows the common
practice of assuming that observed inputs (labor and capital) are homogeneous to production. See Fox and Smeets
(2011) for a study on the role of input heterogeneity in production function estimation.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT