PRODUCT FUNCTIONALITY, COMPETITION, AND MULTIPURCHASING

Published date01 February 2017
AuthorHans Jarle Kind,Simon P. Anderson,Øystein Foros
Date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12213
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 1, February 2017
PRODUCT FUNCTIONALITY, COMPETITION, AND MULTIPURCHASING
BYSIMON P. ANDERSONYSTEIN FOROS,AND HANS JARLE KIND1
University of Virginia, U.S.A; NHH Norwegian School of Economics, Norway;
NHH Norwegian School of Economics, Norway
The more functionalities a good offers, the greater is its perceived quality. Equilibrium prices in standard spatial
competition models depend solely on quality differences. We assume that new functionalities are more appreciated
the closer a product is to a consumer’s ideal variety. Prices are then increasing in functionality levels. Furthermore, we
endogenize whether consumers buy only one of two varieties (single-purchase) or both (multipurchase). Under multi-
purchase, there might be a hump-shaped relationship between equilibrium prices and functionality levels. Therefore,
it could be optimal for each supplier to sacrifice sales and set prices so high that multipurchase is eliminated.
1. INTRODUCTION
Some consumers buy different variants of horizontally differentiated goods (multipurchasing)
like cars, newspapers, and software programs, whereas others buy only one (single-purchasing).
As an example, there are people who install Scientific Workplace as well as Mathematica on
their computers, but others are not willing to pay for both—and installing two copies of the
same software on a computer adds no benefit.
For hardware, compare smartphones (e.g., iPhone or HTC) and multipurpose computer
tablets (such as Windows Surface or Apple iPad). Most smartphones and multipurpose tablets
offer attributes like the ability to play games, make phone calls, read e-mails, watch videos,
and listen to music. One source of horizontal differentiation is the physical size. Compared to
a smartphone, a tablet-like surface is superior for watching videos when sitting in the armchair
at home, but a smartphone is significantly more convenient when traveling.2Many people thus
end up buying both a smartphone and a tablet.3Likewise, a lot of consumers buy both an iPad
and a Kindle.
In a press release (December 27, 2010) Amazon.com’s founder and CEO Jeff Bezos said that
“We’re seeing that many of the people who are buying Kindles also own an LCD tablet (e.g.
an iPad). Customers report using their LCD tablets for games, movies, and web browsing and
their Kindles for reading sessions. They report preferring Kindle for reading because it weighs
less, eliminates battery anxiety with its month-long battery life, and has the advanced paper-like
Pearl e-ink display that reduces eye-strain, doesn’t interfere with sleep patterns at bedtime, and
works outside in direct sunlight, an important consideration especially for vacation reading.”
These devices thus have different attributes, so multipurchasing provides incremental value
over buying just one. But what will happen in the market place in the future if both these goods
Manuscript received January 2014; revised June 2015.
1We thank Fang Guo and Yiyi Zhou for spirited research assistance. Furthermore, we thank participants at the 10th
World Congress of the Econometric Society, August 21, 2010, Shanghai, China; the Conference on Platform Markets:
Regulation and Competition Policy, June 1, 2010, Mannheim, Germany; the 8th IIOC, May 16, 2010, Vancouver,
Canada; and EARIE, September 2, 2011, Stockholm, Sweden, for helpful comments. Please address correspondence
to: Hans Jarle Kind, Department of Economics, NHH, Norwegian School of Economics, Helleveien 30, Bergen, Bergen
5045, Norway. Phone: +4795739837. E-mail: hans.kind@nhh.no.
2Due to their size, tablets are awkward for conventional voice telephony, but may be superior to smartphones for
video conferences.
3See the discussion by Mies, PCWorld April 4, 2010, “iPad Versus the iPhone.” URL: http://www.pcworld.com/
article/193420/ipad_versus_the_iphone_why_i_dont_need_bothyet.html
183
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
184 ANDERSON,FOROS,AND KIND
are improved and offer more attributes?4How might this affect prices and profits, and will
multipurchasing become more or less likely? How does competition play out if each good offers
exclusive attributes compared to if there is a substantial overlap in the attributes the goods offer
(shared attributes)? These are among the questions we address in this article.
Most economic analysis of discrete choice assumes that consumers buy one unit of at most one
variant (see Anderson et al., 1992). Yet the examples above suggest that there are many cases
of purchase of (one unit of) several variants. For each variant, its attractiveness is increasing
in its attributes: An attribute or function (we shall use these terms interchangeably) could be
a particular mathematical tool in a software program, a web browsing opportunity or an e-ink
display on a tablet. A consumer will buy several variants to the extent that this increases the
number of different attributes she can access.5Thus, for any given consumer we might observe
unit demand (at most) for any particular variant, but bringing both an iPad and a Kindle on a
journey might be useful.
The Hotelling model is the workhorse for analyzing unit demand when goods are horizontally
differentiated. We follow this line, but make two innovations. First, we assume that consumers
have a higher willingness to pay for a good the greater the set of attributes it offers. Specifically,
the more satisfied a consumer is with the horizontal characteristics of a good, the greater will be
her marginal utility of having access to more functions (vertical characteristics). On the tablet
market, for instance, it is likely that when Amazon introduced a Kindle with a color screen
opportunity, then the increased willingness to pay for that device was more pronounced for a
Kindle lover than for an iPad lover.6For comparison with more conventional models, it should
be noted that if the set of attributes increases, then also the perceived quality of the good
improves.
Our second innovation is to make single-purchase or multipurchase an endogenous outcome
that depends on consumer preferences, the functionalities of the goods, and the strategic choices
by the suppliers. We take into account that for a multipurchasing consumer, the incremental
value from exclusive attributes (not offered by the rival) is typically higher than for overlapping
(shared) attributes.
Our first innovation implies that the higher the functionality level of the goods, the higher their
prices under single-purchase. In standard symmetric Hotelling models, prices are independent
of the (vertical) quality level. In contrast, product functionality, in the present model, interacts
with the distance-based utility, so functionality is not a pure measure of vertical differentiation.
This feature is also germane to more traditional circumstances with a single discrete choice
between the variants offered.
Noting that prices increase in the functionality levels under single-purchase, it is appropriate
to ask whether there is reason to believe that the same holds under multipurchasing. At the
outset one might think so, but actually the opposite could be true. To see why, suppose that
Apple improves iPad’s e-book reading quality and that Kindle becomes more of a multipurpose
tablet. This will clearly increase the stand-alone value of each of the devices. However, it could
also reduce the incremental value of having an iPad in addition to a Kindle (and vice versa). Put
differently, although the attractiveness of the goods clearly increases in the functionality they
offer, more shared functionality may also make it less imperative for consumers to multipur-
chase. Consistent with this, we show that there might be a hump-shaped relationship between
equilibrium prices and functionality under multipurchase. One implication of this is that if a
sufficiently large number of the functionalities are shared (and the incremental value of shared
4With Kindle Fire, Amazon introduced a version of its e-book reader with more attributes. Kindle Fire is closer to
a multipurpose tablet-like iPad, thereby reducing the incremental value of having both.
5With due tribute to Lancaster (1966) for emphasizing the importance of the characteristics embodied in goods as
the fundamental objects of desire.
6To our knowledge, the only paper to use a similar formulation is Waterman (1989–90). He allows quality to
interact with transportation costs in an extension of his analysis of the trade-off between quality and variety in a circle
framework. However, he does not focus on the features of the formulation highlighted here. Another related paper is
Bonatti (2011), who analyzes nonlinear pricing when consumer quality valuation is brand specific.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT