PLAYING THE FERTILITY GAME AT WORK: AN EQUILIBRIUM MODEL OF PEER EFFECTS

Date01 August 2016
AuthorMarianne Simonsen,Amalia R. Miller,Federico Ciliberto,Helena Skyt Nielsen
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12177
Published date01 August 2016
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 3, August 2016
PLAYING THE FERTILITY GAME AT WORK: AN EQUILIBRIUM MODEL
OF PEER EFFECTS
BYFEDERICO CILIBERTO,AMALIA R. MILLER,HELENA SKYT NIELSEN,
AND MARIANNE SIMONSEN1
University of Virginia, U.S.A.;University of Virginia, U.S.A.; Aarhus University, Denmark;
Aarhus University, Denmark
We study workplace peer effects in fertility decisions using a game theory model of strategic interactions among
coworkers that allows for multiple equilibria. Using register-based data on fertile-aged women working in medium-
sized establishments in Denmark, we uncover negative average peer effects. Allowing for heterogeneous effects by
worker type, we find that positive effects dominate across worker types defined by age or education. Negative effects
dominate within age groups and among low-education types. Policy simulations show that these estimated effects make
the distribution of where women work an important consideration, beyond simply if they work, in predicting population
fertility.
1. INTRODUCTION
The demographic transition to lower fertility rates may have been a catalyst for sustained
economic growth in previous centuries (Galor, 2005), but subreplacement fertility rates are now
a major policy concern in much of the industrialized world. Fertility decisions affect the size
and composition of the population. Reduced or delayed childbearing in the present leads to
population aging and higher ratios of retired to working populations. Hence, very low fertility
rates present challenges for the financing of public and private pension schemes (Borsch-Supan,
2000; Blake and Mayhew, 2006), for redistribution under the welfare state (Rangel, 2003),
and for overall economic growth (Lindh and Malmberg, 1999). Governments in Europe and
elsewhere have sought to increase the size of the workforce by enacting policies that encourage
fertility (through regulation or public spending; Grant et al., 2004; Mumford, 2007) or that
encourage women to enter the paid labor market. Because female labor market participation
is generally associated with lower fertility, these two policies may be in conflict.
This article studies peer effects in the fertility decisions of working women. Measuring work-
place peer effects in fertility can improve our understanding of how female labor market par-
ticipation affects population fertility rates. If peer effects are important, and either positive or
negative, their presence implies that a new workplace factor should be introduced into fertility
models: where women work may matter as much as if they work. In addition to their direct
Manuscript received May 2014; revised March 2015.
1We thank Steve Durlauf, Leora Friedberg, Bryan Graham, Ed Olsen, John Pepper, and participants at the AEA
meetings, CIREQ Applied Economics Conference on Fertility and Child Development, Economic Demography Work-
shop at the Population Association of America meetings, Nordic Summer Institute, Aarhus University, Mount Holyoke
College, Rice University, University of Houston, and University of Oklahoma for insightful comments and suggestions.
We thank Søren Brøgger and Anders Tofthøj for excellent research assistance. This research was supported by the
NIH National Institute of Child Health and Human Development (1R03HD061514), the Dean of the College of Arts
and Sciences and the Vice President for Research and Graduate Studies at the University of Virginia, the Villum
Foundation, and the Danish Research Council (275-09-0020). Part of this work was completed while Miller worked at
the RAND Corporation. The contents of this article are solely the responsibility of the authors and do not necessarily
represent the views of the NIH or other sponsors.
Please address correspondence to: Federico Ciliberto, Department of Economics, University of Virginia,
Charlottesville, VA 22904. E-mail: ciliberto@virginia.edu.
827
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
828 CILIBERTO ET AL.
effects, peer effects in fertility may be important for mediating the impact of policy and other
demographic changes on overall population fertility and fertility of different groups of women.
Previous studies have discussed how positive peer effects can amplify or dampen fertility re-
sponses to changes in the policy or economic environment (e.g., Kohler, 2001; Kravdal, 2002;
Bloom et al., 2008). An example of a dampening story is the argument in Moffitt (1998) and
Murray (1993) that social stigma (associated with out-of-wedlock childbearing) reduced the
short-term fertility responses to changes in fertility incentives in U.S. welfare policies. An am-
plification story is in Montgomery and Casterline (1998), who argue that multiplier effects from
social learning and social influences hastened demographic transitions, through the diffusion of
contraceptive technologies.
Following the economics literature on fertility, we model childbearing as a rational choice,
responsive to financial incentives (Becker, 1960; Willis, 1973). However, unlike most of that
literature, which studies decisions at the level of individual women or couples,2we explore
peer effects in an equilibrium framework for peer groups of women working at the same
establishment. This emphasis aligns with the shift in economic demography to consider social
influences on fertility decisions. Studies have found evidence of peer effects using geographic
areas or neighborhoods (Crane, 1991; South and Baumer, 2000; Bloom et al., 2008), schools
(Evans et al., 1992), ethnic or religious groups (Manski and Mayshar, 2003), families (Kuziemko,
2006), and networks of friends (Behrman et al., 2002) as their primary social unit. A common
feature of these studies is their focus on social or informational factors leading to positive peer
effects. In contrast, this article studies interactions in fertility decisions among female coworkers
at the same physical work establishment that could be positive or negative.
One motivation for studying the workplace is precisely this variation. Unlike the usual social
effects that tend to increase similarity among friends or neighbors, the workplace setting contains
a complex mix of social and economic interactions that can produce positive or negative peer
effects in fertility. A second motivation is the dramatic increase over the last half-century in
the share of prime-age women working for pay, which has made the workplace an increasingly
important setting in which to study women’s fertility decisions. Third, the workplace can be
used to define peer groups of individuals who work for the same organization at the same
physical location and are potentially exposed to one another for several hours a day. Although
workplace peer groups are primarily structured around economic production goals, a new set
of studies has found evidence of peer effects at the workplace involving various behaviors other
than fertility, including productivity (Mas and Moretti, 2009; Bandiera et al., 2010), charitable
contributions (Carman, 2003), retirement savings (Duflo and Saez, 2003), and paternity-leave
taking (Dahl et al., 2014).3
We model the interactions at a workplace among women deciding whether to have children
as a complete information, simultaneous, static, discrete choice (“entry”) game and solve for
the Nash equilibrium outcomes.4In an equilibrium of the game, each woman is maximizing
her utility by having a child or not, taking the actions of coworkers as given; this implies an
inequality condition for each woman. The full set of inequality conditions at each workplace is
2See Hotz et al. (1997) for a survey of the literature on the economics of fertility in developed countries. More
recent studies have revisited the relationship between household income and demand for children (e.g., Lovenheim
and Mumford, 2013) and the impact of redistributive policy on fertility (e.g., Kearney, 2004).
3Dahl et al. (2014) find peer effects within both families and workplaces.
4The assumption of complete information has the attractive features of capturing the reality that agents in the
model likely have information about the payoff functions of their coworkers that is not available to econometricians
and allows us to avoid the possibility of ex post regret that could arise with incomplete information. In a static game
of incomplete information, agents may experience ex post regret, which we do not think as plausible in a long-run
equilibrium. Also, the challenge of multiple equilibria that we address here would not necessarily be avoided in a static
game with incomplete information (e.g., Berry and Tamer, 2006; Berry and Reiss, 2007). Finally, Grieco (2014) rejects
a model where agents only have incomplete information, whereas he cannot reject a model where agents have only
complete information. This is because, as Grieco (2014, p. 312) explains, “the model is at the height of its flexibility
under the complete information assumption—multiple equilibria is most common and different equilibria allow the
widest range of equilibrium entry probabilities.”

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT