OVERVALUED: SWEDISH MONETARY POLICY IN THE 1930s

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12254
Date01 November 2017
AuthorAlexander Rathke,Ulrich Woitek,Tobias Straumann
Published date01 November 2017
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 4, November 2017
OVERVALUED: SWEDISH MONETARY POLICY IN THE 1930s
BYALEXANDER RATHKE,TOBIAS STRAUMANN,AND ULRICH WOITEK1
KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich, Switzerland, and CESifo, Germany; University of
Zurich, Switzerland; University of Zurich, Switzerland, and CESifo, Germany
The article discusses Sweden’s monetary policy in the 1930s, which has been hailed as the first and only
example of successful price-level targeting. Our contribution is twofold. First, we argue that the crucial measure
that immediately ended deflationary expectations and enabled a swift recovery was a strong and involuntary
devaluation of the currency, not the adoption of a new monetary policy framework. Second, starting from the
recent literature on monetary policy at the zero-lower bound, we conclude that Sweden’s exchange rate policy
is more relevant for the current discussion than its tentative experience with price-level targeting.
1. INTRODUCTION
The recent financial crisis has led to a discussion about the effectiveness of monetary policy
at the zero lower bound. One of the proposals that has received much attention is price-level
targeting as an alternative to inflation targeting. Notably, Charles L. Evans, President of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, joined the ranks of those advocating a “state-contingent
price-level target.” According to him, it would help the public’s understanding of the Fed’s
intentions in the current situation if the central bank clearly communicated “an expected path
for prices” (Evans, 2012, p. 147). Blanchard et al. (2013, p. 10) argued that a price-level target
“would allow for higher inflation rates without undermining central bank credibility in the long
run.” And, in 2014, Narayana Kocherlakota, then President of the Federal Reserve Bank of
Minneapolis, showed some sympathy for price-level targeting (Kocherlakota, 2014).2
The current discussion about price-level targeting is linked to the academic research on the
long stagnation of the Japanese economy since the early 1990s. Several macroeconomists have
developed new ideas in order to improve the effectiveness of monetary policy at the zero
lower bound (e.g., Krugman, 1998; Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003). Svensson (2003) provides
a useful summary of all these suggestions and formulates a “foolproof way to escape from
a liquidity trap.” Svensson lists three conditions for a successful strategy: an upward-sloping
price-level target path, a depreciation and a crawling peg of the currency, and an exit strategy.
The gist of his argument is that communicating an upward-sloping price-level target path is
not sufficient—in addition, depreciation is needed as a credible commitment to an increase in
the future price level, which in turn leads to a reduction in the real interest rate by changing
expectations.
This article tries to make a historical contribution to the ongoing debate about alternative
monetary policy regimes. It discusses Sweden’s monetary policy in the 1930s that is said to have
Manuscript received March 2012; revised November 2015.
1We would like to thank the editor, two anonymous referees, Stephen Broadberry, Marc Flandreau, Riitta Hjerppe,
Mathias Hoffmann, Peter Kugler, James Malley, Peter Rosenkranz, Samad Sarferaz, Lennart Sch¨
on, Bent Sørensen,
and participants at various seminars and conferences for very helpful comments and suggestions. Please address
correspondence to: Alexander Rathke, KOF Swiss Economic Institute, ETH Zurich, Leonhardstrasse 21, CH-8092
Zurich, Switzerland. Phone: +41 44 632 8623. Fax: +41 44 632 1218. E-mail: rathke@kof.ethz.ch.
2See Ambler (2009), B¨
ohm et al. (2012), and Hatcher and Minford (2014) for a survey of the literature on pioneering
work on price-level targeting. For a thorough discussion of new approaches to monetary policy, see, e.g., English et al.
(2013).
1355
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT