OPTIMAL COST OVERRUNS: PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS WITH RENEGOTIATION

Published date01 November 2018
AuthorMarco A. Schwarz,Fabian Herweg
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12327
Date01 November 2018
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 59, No. 4, November 2018 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12327
OPTIMAL COST OVERRUNS: PROCUREMENT AUCTIONS
WITH RENEGOTIATION
BYFABIAN HERWEG AND MARCO A. SCHWARZ1
University of Bayreuth, CESifo, Germany, CEPR, UK; University of Innsbruck, Austria
Cost overrun is ubiquitous in public procurement. We argue that this can be the result of a constrained
optimal award procedure: The procurer awards the contract via a price-only auction and cannot commit not to
renegotiate. If cost differences are more pronounced for a fancy than a standard design, it is optimal to fix the
standard design ex ante. If renegotiation takes place and the fancy design has higher production costs or the
contractor’s bargaining position is strong, the final price exceeds the initial price. Moreover, the procurer cannot
benefit from using a scoring auction.
1. INTRODUCTION
Renegotiation of procurement contracts awarded by public authorities is ubiquitous. The
initial contract is awarded via competitive tendering; that is, via an auction. The terms of the
initial contract, however, are often subject to renegotiation, with the result that the ultimate
price is (by far) higher than the price that the parties initially agreed upon. Prominent recent
examples of public procurement projects that are by far more expensive than initially planned
are the Elbphilharmonie, a concert hall in Hamburg, the Big Dig, a highway artery in Boston,
and the North–South metro line in Amsterdam.2What is often considered as the most severe
case of a cost overrun in modern construction history is the Sydney Opera House.3The project
was completed 10 years late at a price of 14.6 times the initial price.4During the construction of
the Sydney Opera House, plenty of design changes had taken place. For instance, the design of
the roof has been changed from a relatively flat roof to the fancy ribbed ellipsoidal roof, which
Manuscript received July 2016; revised October 2017.
1We thank the editor, Masaki Aoyagi, three anonymous referees, Mikhail Anufriev, Alessandro De Chiara, Dominik
Fischer, Jacob Goeree, Heiko Karle, Laurent Lamy, Laurent Linnemer, Johannes Maier, Antonio Rosato, Klaus
M. Schmidt, Johannes Schneider, Heiner Schumacher, and Christoph Schwaiger for many helpful comments and
suggestions. We would also like to thank the seminar and conference participants at EARIE Maastricht, KU Leuven,
UC Louvain-la-Neuve, DICE D¨
usseldorf, Mannheim University, Carlos III de Madrid, Frankfurt School of Finance
& Management, Theoretischer Ausschuss at Basel, X-CREST Paris, University of Bern, University of Munich, and
University of Technology Sydney. Part of this research was conducted while the first author visited the University of
Technology Sydney, and Fabian would like to thank the Business School for its great hospitality. Financial support from
the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft through SFB/TR 15 and CRC/TRR 190 and from the Austrian Science Fund
(SFB F63) are gratefully acknowledged. Please address correspondence to: Fabian Herweg, University of Bayreuth,
Faculty of Law, Business and Economics, International Competition Policy, Universitaetsstr. 30 95447 Bayreuth,
Germany. E-mail: fabian.herweg@uni-bayreuth.de.
2Regarding the Elbphilharmonie, the accepted offer from the underwriting group in 2006 was 241 million euro. The
final price at the handover of keys in 2016 was 789 million euro (Fiedler and Schuster, 2016). For the Amsterdam metro
line, the initial budget was set at 1.46 billion euro in 2002 but the costs had risen to 3.1 billion euro in 2009. Recent
estimates suggest that it will be completed in 2017 (Chang et al., 2016). For the Boston highway artery, the ultimate
price exceeded the initial price by 1.6 billion U.S. dollars (Bajari et al., 2014).
3We define as cost overrun the difference between the final price and the initial price at which the procurement
order has been awarded.
4When controlling for inflation, the cost overrun reduces to a factor of 7.5 (Newton et al., 2014).
1995
C
(2018) The Authors. International Economic Review published by Wiley Periodicals, Inc. on behalf of Economics
Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social and Economic Research
Association
This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use,
distribution and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
1996 HERWEG AND SCHWARZ
increased the cost for the roof by 65%. This and other changes that arguably made the Sydney
Opera House more complex are responsible for a part of its cost overrun.5
Next to casual observations, empirical studies document that the prices typically increase
through renegotiation.6According to public opinion, these cost overruns are a sign of inefficient
project management by bureaucrats or of strategizing politicians and thus a waste of taxpayers’
money. In contrast to this widespread public opinion, we argue that these seemingly inefficient
cost overruns can be the result of a constrained optimal award procedure that minimizes the
expected final price for the procurer.
In our model, a procurer needs an indivisible good or service, which can take one of two
designs, that is, a standard (low quality) or a “fancy” (high quality) design (a bridge with
two or three traffic lanes). The good can be delivered by several suppliers who may differ in
their privately known production costs. Moreover, the ex post efficient design depends on the
contractor’s production cost, that is, on the cost type of the supplier who has been awarded
the contract. Initially, the procurer runs an auction to allocate the contract. Importantly, the
contract specified by the auction is a specific performance contract that can be enforced by
courts. First, we assume that the procurer can collect bids only on prices and thus has to select
one particular design of the good. More precisely, the procurement contract for the given
design is awarded to one supplier via a standard auction, for example, a second-price sealed-bid
auction. The design specified in the initial contract may turn out to be inefficient, given the cost
type of the contractor. In this case, we assume that the parties engage in Coasian bargaining
and implement the efficient design ex post. Renegotiation is expected by the suppliers and
thus incorporated in their bidding behavior. The rent the contractor (the supplier who won the
auction) receives depends on his cost advantage compared to the second lowest bidder with
regard to the initial design. We assume that cost differences are more pronounced for the fancy
design than for the standard one. Under this assumption, it is optimal for the procurer to fix
the standard design ex ante because this enhances competition in the initial auction. In other
words, when commitment not to renegotiate is not feasible, it is optimal for the procurer to
choose the standard design ex ante and to potentially renegotiate to the fancy design ex post. If
the cost for producing the fancy design is higher or if the contractor’s bargaining power is not
too weak, the final (renegotiation) price exceeds the initial price, i.e., a cost overrun occurs.
An important feature of our model is that the outcome is always efficient. The supplier who
can deliver the ex post efficient design at the lowest cost wins the auction. He benefits most
from contract renegotiation and thus bids most aggressively. This implies that the unique goal
of the procurer is rent extraction, i.e., choosing the initial design such that the expected final
price—for the overall efficient design delivered by the most efficient supplier—is minimized. In
other words, the procurer does not face a rent extraction versus efficiency trade-off.
Due to the assumption of Coasian bargaining ex post, the ex post outcome is always efficient
in our baseline model. In two extensions, we augment the baseline model and allow for renego-
tiation failure. First, we consider the situation where contract renegotiation takes place under
asymmetric information. Focusing on a simplified model with only two cost types, we show that
the type is always revealed via the bid. The procurer optimally specifies the standard design
ex ante, and contract renegotiation typically leads to an upward price adjustment. Second, we
analyze what happens when there is an exogenous risk that the renegotiation breaks down and
the parties are stuck with the initial contract. If this risk is rather low, it is still optimal to choose
the standard design ex ante. As the risk becomes larger, taking into account the situation when
renegotiation fails becomes more important, so the optimal initial design is more likely to be
5See Newton et al. (2014) and Drew (1999) for more detailed discussions of the construction and cost increases of
the Sydney Opera House.
6Substantial price increases resulting from contract renegotiation are reported by Decarolis (2014) for Italian pro-
curement contracts and by Bajari et al. (2014) for Californian procurement contracts. German procurement contracts
and their cost increases are listed by Fiedler and Schuster (2016). They also report that some projects perform excep-
tionally well. For instance, the Chemikum, a building of the University of Erlangen-Nuremberg, was completed a year
earlier than planned and at a cost of only 80 million euro instead of the planned 140 million euro.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT