OLIGOPOLY AND COST SHARING IN ECONOMIES WITH PUBLIC GOODS

Published date01 May 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12165
Date01 May 2016
AuthorMaria Gabriella Graziano,Achille Basile,Marialaura Pesce
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 2, May 2016
OLIGOPOLY AND COST SHARING IN ECONOMIES WITH PUBLIC GOODS
BYACHILLE BASILE,MARIA GABRIELLA GRAZIANO,AND MARIALAURA PESCE1
Universit`
a degli Studi di Napoli Federico II, Italy; Universit`
a degli Studi di Napoli Federico II,
Italy and CSEF; Universit`
a degli Studi di Napoli Federico II, Italy and CSEF
We study economies that involve both small and large traders as well as the choice of a public project. Within this
framework, we establish two sufficient conditions under which the set of competitive allocations coincides with the core.
Our first core equivalence result holds under the assumption that there is a countably infinite set of large traders similar
to each other. The second result, independent of the number of large traders, requires the existence of a coalition of
small traders with the same characteristics of the large traders. Finally, we show how the generalized Aubin approach
to cooperation may dispense with both conditions.
1. INTRODUCTION
In a large economy, the core of the market coincides with the set of competitive allocations.
Although the core acknowledges that coalitions of traders may cooperate to improve their own
welfare, a multitude of negligible agents ends up generating the same outcome they would
get by acting as price-takers. Edgeworth conjectured such equivalence of cooperative versus
competitive behavior, later proved in Aumann’s seminal contribution (Aumann, 1964) where
the space of agents is postulated to be a continuum. The ensuing literature sought more re-
alistic assumptions, introducing two major features: (i) nonnegligible market participants and
(ii) public goods.
The first issue looms when traders may concentrate in their hands an initial ownership of
commodities that is sufficiently large with respect to the total market endowment. This is
typical in monopolistic or, more generally, oligopolistic markets. Another case arises when,
while the initial endowment is spread over a continuum of negligible traders, some of them may
join forces and decide to act as a single player on the market. Under any agreement that prevents
further splits in subcoalitions, nonnegligible market participants may organize themselves in
the form of cartels, syndicates, or similar institutions. Since this reduces the number of active
coalitions, the core becomes larger and the equivalence theorem may fail.
In economies with public goods, core equivalence may fail even when all traders are negligible.
Roughly speaking, the intuition is the following: When perfect competition requires a large
number of agents and the per capita cost for a public good is decreasing, this weakens the
influence of small coalitions and makes the core larger. Indeed, if a blocking coalition is expected
to finance the public project by itself, too small coalitions might not be able to cover the
whole cost and, consequently, blocking becomes harder. This happens in the typical setup that
combines the assumption of a uniform distribution among agents for the cost of providing the
public good (as in the Lindahl competitive approach) with a Foley veto mechanism for modeling
the objections underlying the construction of the core (see Foley, 1970).
Manuscript received March 2014; revised July 2014.
1The authors thank the editor and two referees for helpful comments. The financial support from research grants
PRIN 20103S5RN3 “Robust Decision Making in Markets and Organization”and Programma STAR Napoli-call2013-89
“Equilibrium with Ambiguity” is gratefully acknowledged. Please address correspondence to: Achille Basile, Diparti-
mento di Scienze Economiche e Statistiche. Universit`
a degli Studi di Napoli Federico II, Complesso Monte S. Angelo,
Via Cintia, 80126 Napoli, Italy. Tel.: +39 081675104; fax: +39 081675009. E-mail: basile@unina.it.
487
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
488 BASILE,GRAZIANO,AND PESCE
Since either feature may lead to a failure of core equivalence, the literature has provided
several conditions under which the equivalence holds true when one of the two features is
present; see Shitovitz (1973); Mas-Colell (1980); Diamantaras and Gilles (1996); Gilles and
Diamantaras (1998); Weber and Wiesmeth (1991). This article answers the same question when
both features are present; that is, we provide sufficient conditions for core equivalence under
the simultaneous presence of negligible/nonnegligible traders and of collective goods.
This enriched model fits well problems of international cooperation for the provision of a
global public goods (e.g., climate control) where few large players, corresponding to rich coun-
tries, interact with many small traders, corresponding to poor countries; see Buchholz et al.
(2006) and Shitovitz and Spiegel (1998) among others. These situations have attracted much
interest toward the noncooperative provision of public goods (when countries are assumed to
be independent players) as well as toward cooperative solutions coordinated through interna-
tional agreements to overcome the inefficiency of noncooperative policies. To the best of our
knowledge, however, only very little attention has been devoted to a comparison of the two
approaches.
In markets with public goods, the entities that benefit from them (consumers, firms, munic-
ipalities, regions, countries, etc.) are usually different both in the size of their endowments as
well as in their contributive capacity. An additional contribution of our model is that it helps
to manage the dichotomy between small and large traders along with the distinction between
small and large tax-payers (or contributors), clarifying the relations among them.
The main elements in our setup of mixed economy (Shitovitz, 1973) are an atomless sector
of consumers representing the ocean of negligible traders, a set of atoms representing the
influential agents, and a contribution scheme that specifies the cost for the provision of
the public good for individual agents as well as for coalitions. Negligible and influential agents
are defined with respect to the size measure in the agents’ space. Small and large contributors
are similarly defined with respect to the measure underlying the contribution scheme.
We do not assume any mathematical structure for the set of public projects. This choice
does not preclude the standard Euclidean structure, but carries the important advantage of
naturally embedding the case where traders have misaligned preferences over public goods
and a common ordering cannot be assumed. Moreover, if public projects are interpreted as
environments (i.e., collections of variables common to all the agents but determined outside the
market mechanism), this general framework encompasses many different economic problems;
see Diamantaras and Gilles (1996); Gilles and Diamantaras (1998); Diamantaras et al. (1996);
Gilles and Scotchmer (1997); Basile et al. (2005); Graziano (2007); Hammond and Villar (1998),
Hammond and Villar (1999).
Our notion of competitive equilibrium originates in Mas-Colell (1980) and in the subsequent
papers Diamantaras and Gilles (1996) and Gilles and Diamantaras (1998). Compared to Gilles
and Diamantaras (1998), we do not assume that the individual contribution is the same for
each public project. Consequently, our cost share equilibrium allows individual payments to
vary according to individual benefits. This situation naturally arises when a level of provision
is interpreted as a whole configuration of public policies or when cost share functions are
interpreted as voluntary contributions (see Mas-Colell, 1980) instead of predetermined tax
systems. From a technical viewpoint, the cost share equilibrium generalizes the linear cost
share equilibrium introduced in Gilles and Diamantaras (1998), by combining the notion of
cost share function (see Mas-Colell, 1980, and Gilles and Diamantaras, 1998, Definition 2) with
the idea of cost distribution introduced in Gilles and Diamantaras (1998). On the cooperative
side, we borrow the veto mechanism from Gilles and Diamantaras (1998) and Graziano and
Romaniello (2012). This involves a (contribution)measure, defined on the set of all coalitions,
that pinpoints the level of contribution that each blocking coalition is expected to cover. Due
to the motivations above, our model allows that the contribution measure varies across public
projects. Then, we conveniently remold the σ-core of Gilles and Diamantaras (1998) into a
definition of the core, here dubbed weak σ-core, that naturally fits our characterization of cost
share equilibria.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT