OBVIOUSLY STRATEGY‐PROOF IMPLEMENTATION OF TOP TRADING CYCLES

Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12384
AuthorPeter Troyan
Date01 August 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 3, August 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12384
OBVIOUSLY STRATEGY-PROOF IMPLEMENTATION OF TOP TRADING
CYCLES
BYPETER TROYAN1
University of Virginia, U.S.A.
Although there is a rich theoretical literature extolling the virtues of the top trading cycles (TTCs) mechanism,
it is rarely used in practice. Anecdotal evidence suggests that one possible explanation is that TTC is difficult for
participants to understand. This article formalizes this intuition by asking whether it is possible to implement
TTC in an obviously strategy-proof (OSP) way. I identify an acyclicity condition that is both necessary and
sufficient for OSP implementation of TTC. The condition is unlikely to hold in most applications, which may
explain why TTC is rarely used, despite its many appealing theoretical properties.
1. INTRODUCTION
An important consideration when designing institutions to allocate scare resources is the
incentives given to agents to report their preferences truthfully. For example, in school choice,
it is well known that the so-called “Boston” mechanism gives students (or their parents) very
clear incentives to lie about their true preference and can harm students who may be unable
to strategize appropriately. Because of this, economists have generally advised against using
manipulable mechanisms such as the Boston mechanism in favor of mechanisms that ensure it
is always an optimal strategy for agents to report their true preferences; in other words, they
recommend that the mechanism be strategy-proof.2
There are three canonical strategy-proof ways to assign indivisible objects in the absence
of transfers that are used in practice: serial dictatorship (SD), deferred acceptance (DA), and
top trading cycles (TTCs). However, just because a mechanism is strategy-proof in theory does
not mean that participants will be truthful in practice. The agents participating in it must also
understand that it is strategy-proof.
One formalization of what it means for participants to “understand” that a mechanism is
strategy-proof is the concept of obvious strategy-proofness(OSP) due to Li (2017). A mechanism
is OSP if each agent has an obviously dominant strategy, which, informally, is a strategy such
that even the worst possible outcome from following it is better than the best case from any
possible deviation. Li (2017) shows that obviously dominant strategies are those that can be
seen as optimal by a cognitively limited agent who cannot engage in contingent reasoning.
For no-transfer settings like those considered in this article, Li (2017) shows that SDs are
OSP when implemented dynamically and provides experimental evidence that rates of truth
telling are higher when using such a dynamic implementation compared to a static one, which
Manuscript received November 2017; revised July 2018.
1I would like to thank Itai Ashlagi, Yannai Gonczarowski, Fuhito Kojima, and Marek Pycia for helpful conversations
relating to this project, as well as the editor, Rakesh Vohra, and anonymous referees for comments that have improved
the article. Please address correspondence to: Peter Troyan, Department of Economics, University of Virginia, P.O.
Box 400182, Charlottesville, VA 22904. E-mail: troyan@virginia.edu.
2Pathak and S ¨
onmez (2008) argue that nonstrategy-proof mechanisms may harm parents who are unable to strategize
well, and incentive considerations were key concerns for the New York City and Boston school districts when deciding
upon which mechanism to use (Abdulkadiro˘
glu et al., 2005a, 2005b). At the same time, strategy-proofness is not without
costs, and recent literature has begun to reexamine nonstrategy-proof mechanisms such as the Boston mechanism and
show that they may outperform strategy-proof mechanisms from an ex ante perspective in some settings, at least under
equilibrium play (e.g., Miralles, 2009; Abdulkadiro˘
glu et al., 2011; Troyan, 2012; Featherstone and Niederle, 2016).
1249
C
(2019) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT