NONNEUTRALITY OF MONEY IN DISPERSION: HUME REVISITED

AuthorTao Zhu,Gu Jin
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12387
Published date01 August 2019
Date01 August 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 3, August 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12387
NONNEUTRALITY OF MONEY IN DISPERSION: HUME REVISITED
BYGUJIN AND TAO ZHU1
Central University of Finance and Economics, China; Hong Kong University of Science
and Technology, Hong Kong
For a class of standard and widely used preferences, a one-shot money injection in a standard matching model
can induce a significant and persistent output response by dispersing the distribution of wealth. Decentralized
trade matters for both persistence and significance. Following the injection, the price response may be sluggish,
the markup may move up with output, and both the interest rate and the inflation rate may drop below their
trend levels.
1. INTRODUCTION
First published in 1752, Of Money articulates Hume’s view of nonneutrality of money that
has been influential for centuries:
When any quantity of money is imported into a nation, it is not at first dispersed into many hands; but
is confined to the coffers of a few persons, who immediately seek to employ it to advantage. . .. It is
easy to trace the money in its progress through the whole commonwealth; where we shall find, that it
must first quicken the diligence of every individual, before it encrease the price of labour. (Hume, 1987,
p. 172)
Often present in modern writings (see, e.g., Friedman 1987; Lucas 1996; Wallace 1997), this
passage seems to relate a stimulating effect of a money injection to (a) a limited participation
in the market from which money is injected and (b) a dispersion (i.e., diffusion) process in
the market from which injected money gradually reaches all people in the economy. But is
there any mechanism by which a limited participation and a dispersion process can make
an injection stimulating? Here we explore such a mechanism against the familiar matching
model of Trejos and Wright (1995) and Shi (1995) with general individual money holdings, a
model that accommodates a limited participation by nondegenerate wealth distributions and
a gradual dispersion process by decentralized trade.2We apply a class of standard and widely
used preferences for quantitative exercises and concentrate on one-shot money injections.
Our parameterized model has two salient features. First, aggregate output would increase in a
steady state if people’s incentives to trade were not changed, but the distribution of wealth were
more dispersed. The main force behind is simple and intuitive: a reduction in a poor seller’s
wealth results in a much larger increment in production than a reduction in a rich seller’s.
Second, people’s incentives along a transition path to the steady state are very close to their
incentives in the steady state. These two features imply that if a redistributional shock disperses
Manuscript received November 2017; revised August 2018.
1We are thankful to two anonymous referees for their valuable comments that have improved the article. Zhu
acknowledges the support by RGC, Hong Kong under the grant GRF647911. Please address correspondence to: Tao
Zhu, Department of Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Clear Water Bay, Kowloon, Hong
Kong. Phone: 852-2358-7601. E-mail: taozhu@ust.hk
2The canonical form of the model, one with divisible money and with no upper bound on the individual holdings,
has a central role in the New Monetarism literature (see Williamson and Wright, 2010) in that much of the literature is
built on its tractable versions, for example, Lagos and Wright (2005) and Shi (1997).
1329
C
(2019) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1330 JIN AND ZHU
(stretches) the steady-state distribution of money but maintains the quantity of money, there is
an immediate significant output response.
Decentralized trade obviously adds persistence to the output response by slowing down the
dispersion (diffusion) of redistributed money, and it has a more critical role. Suppose that a
competitive market substitutes for decentralized trade as in a Bewley model. If there is no
change in the price level, then the wealth redistribution may still have the same output effect as
above; but for the market to clear, nominal prices must fall below the steady-state level in the
transition path, which, in turn, dilutes sellers’ incentives to produce and dampens the output
response. That is, a wealth redistribution is able to exploit the steady-state incentives to trade—
in particular, poorer sellers’ much stronger incentives to produce—because these incentives are
preserved by decentralized trade in the transition path.
A money injection can disperse the wealth distribution when it is regressive. As output,
the price in each meeting along the transition path is very close to the meeting price in the
postinjection steady state. The injection may redistribute the mass of meetings so that aggregate
output moves above the postinjection steady-state level (which is equal to the preinjection
steady-state level) and the average price across meetings moves below the postinjection steady
state level (which increases from the preinjection steady-state level proportionally to the change
in the quantity of money). Thus, a positive output response may co-occur with nominal rigidity,
but the co-occurrence does not mean causality in either way.
To discipline our exercises, we endogenize regressiveness of each money injection by endog-
enizing a limited participation (in receiving injected money). With a unitary CRRA coefficient
and a unitary Frisch elasticity of labor supply, a 1% accumulative increase in the money stock
can induce a more than 4% accumulative increase in output over 20 quarters. There is a Phillips
curve in that the output and price responses are proportional to the increase in the money stock.
For plausible parameter values, nominal rigidity emerges, and the markup moves up with out-
put. When the model includes nominal government bonds (issued before pairwise meetings and
financed by inflation), the injection keeps to induce a significant and persistent output response;
following the injection, there is a liquidity effect, and the inflation rate may first drop below the
trend level, a phenomenon analogous to the price puzzle found by VAR studies.
It is not new that a money injection is nonneutral when it redistributes wealth (see Friedman,
1969).3But, as is well known, redistributing wealth or not, monetary shocks do not generate
significant and persistent output responses in a large class of models absent of imposed nominal
rigidity (see, e.g., Chari et al., 2000). Although one may therefore choose to impose nominal
rigidity on a model, there is always criticism of the assumption that people cannot change prices
when they want.4In this context, our contribution is to show that flexible price can be consistent
with the output-response pattern in concern and that nominal rigidity may not be the cause but
may be a part of nonneutrality of money.
We spell out the basic model, parameterization, and the procedure for quantitative exercises
in Section 2. Section 3 demonstrates the two salient features of the model and the critical role
of decentralized trade. The one-shot regressive injection is introduced in Section 4. The model
with bonds is analyzed in Section 5. In Section 6, we offer some discussion of our model and
future works.
2. THE BASIC MODEL
The model is the one formulated by Trejos and Wright (1995) and Shi (1995) with general
individual money holdings. Time is discrete, dated as t0. There is a unit mass of infinitely
lived agents. At each period, each agent has the equal chance to be a buyer or a seller. Each
3Notably, redistribution effects are explored by the early and some late contributions in the limited-participation
literature; see, for example, Grossman and Weiss (1983), Rotemberg (1984), Alvarez et al. (2002), and Williamson
(2008, 2009).
4See Head et al. (2012) for a comprehensive review of the literature.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT