NEW EXPORTER DYNAMICS

AuthorJonathan L. Willis,Kim J. Ruhl
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12232
Date01 August 2017
Published date01 August 2017
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 3, August 2017
NEW EXPORTER DYNAMICS
BYKIM J. RUHL AND JONATHAN L. WILLIS1
Pennsylvania State University, U.S.A; Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, U.S.A.
We document that new exporters initially export small amounts, grow gradually, and are most likely to exit
the export market in their first few years. We find that the standard sunk-cost model cannot replicate these new
exporter dynamics: New exporters grow too large too quickly and live too long. In a modified sunk-cost model
that can account for these facts, the entry costs needed to match the data are three times smaller than in the
sunk-cost model. Dynamic models with richer plant-level heterogeneity are needed.
1. INTRODUCTION
Models in which heterogeneous plants face fixed export entry costs have become important
tools for studying international trade patterns, measuring trade frictions, and evaluating policy.2
These models, which are typically focused on steady-state analysis, have been successful in
replicating several key features of the plant-level data in the cross section, such as the low
export participation rate and the fact that exporters are larger than nonexporters.
Although the steady-state properties of this class of models have provided insight into the
plant’s export decision, the presence of a sunk entry cost makes the dynamic content of these
models extremely rich.3The key innovation in the dynamic models is that plants enter and
exit the foreign market in response to changes in relative prices and productivity. In seminal
work, Baldwin (1988), Baldwin and Krugman (1989), and Dixit (1989) demonstrated that the
hysteresis implied by these models is important for understanding the effects of large and
small exchange rate movements. More recent work has incorporated this type of industrial
structure into stochastic dynamic models disciplined by increasingly accessible plant-level data.
For example, Ghironi and Melitz (2005) and Alessandria and Choi (2007) use these types of
models to study how the inclusion of plants’ exporting decisions affects real exchange rate and
net export dynamics over business cycles, and Ruhl (2008) demonstrates how export entry can
produce asymmetric responses to temporary and permanent changes in expected export profits.
Das et al. (2007) estimate a dynamic structural model of export entry and exit and use it to study
the impact of trade policy. These models have typically focused on the aggregate implications
of export entry and exit.
In this article, we ask whether sunk-cost models can reproduce the dynamics of new exporters.
We begin by using plant-level data on Colombian manufacturers to document two key properties
of new exporter behavior. First, we show that new exporters begin by exporting small amounts
Manuscript received July 2014; revised March 2016.
1We would like to thank George Alessandria, Costas Arkolakis, Roc Armenter, Tim Kehoe, and two anonymous
referees for helpful comments. We thank Mark Roberts and Jim Tybout for access to the Colombian plant data.
This work was undertaken with the support of the National Science Foundation under grant SES-0536970. The views
expressed herein are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve Bank
of Kansas City.
Please address correspondence to: Kim J. Ruhl, Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, 615 Kern
Building, University Park, PA 16802. E-mail: kjr42@psu.edu.
2Notable papers in this expansive literature include Melitz (2003), Helpman et al. (2008), and Eaton et al. (2011).
3In this class of models, a plant pays a fixed entry cost to enter the export market (f0) and a fixed cost in each period
thereafter to continue exporting (f1). The difference between the two (f0f1) is the part of the entry cost that is
irrecoverable—the part of the entry cost that is sunk.
703
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
704 RUHL AND WILLIS
Ratio of exports to total sales
0 1 2 3 4
0.00
0.03
0.06
0.09
0.12
0.15
0.18
years since export entry
export−total sales ratio
Continuing exporter average (data)
New exporter average (data)
Conditional survival rate
0 1 2 3 4
0.50
0.60
0.70
0.80
0.90
1.00
years since export entry
conditional survival rate
New exporters (data)
All exporters (data)
(a) (b)
FIGURE 1
NEW EXPORTER DYNAMICS [COLOR FIGURE CAN BE VIEWED AT WILEYONLINELIBRARY.COM]
relative to total production and—conditional on continuing in the export market—gradually
expand their export volumes over several years. This can be seen in Figure 1(a), in which we
plot the average export to total sales ratio (the export–sales ratio) of the new exporters in our
sample. Second, we show that, compared to plants that have exported for several years, new
exporters are more likely to exit the export market. In Figure 1(b), we plot the share of plants
that export a+1 years after entry, conditional on having exported for ayears. It takes three
years for a new exporter’s survival rate to level off. Our two findings have been subsequently
confirmed in other data: Kohn et al. (2016), for example, document similar patterns among
Chilean manufacturers.
Next, we construct a dynamic stochastic model of a plant’s export decision and calibrate it to
the cross-sectional facts that are commonly used to parameterize fixed entry cost models. We
find that the model cannot—either qualitatively or quantitatively—reproduce the behavior of
new exporters that we observe in the data. In the model, as opposed to the data, an exporter
sells the most in the export market (relative to its total sales) in its first periods of exporting,
and there is no gradual growth in export sales in subsequent years. The model is also unable
to generate exit rates that decline with the number of years that a plant has exported. In the
model, a plant is least likely to exit the foreign market in its first few years of exporting.
The failure of the standard sunk-cost model to capture the dynamics of new exporters is
important. The present value of exporting—the key determinant of export entry—is fundamen-
tal to understanding both the plant-level and the aggregate responses to trade policy and to
measuring export barriers, such as the costs of export entry. The present value of exporting is
determined by both how long a plant expects to stay in the export market and when export
profits are realized. By generating new exporters that live too long and export too much too
soon, the model significantly overestimates the value of exporting. At the plant level, this im-
plies that the estimated export entry costs will be overstated, which we quantify in Section 6.
Export entry costs fall by a factor of three when we augment the sunk-cost model so that export
volumes grow as slowly as they do in the data.4Although the estimated entry cost falls when we
account for new exporter dynamics, this does not mean that sunk-costs are no longer important.
We still estimate that a significant portion of the entry cost is sunk.
Why does the sunk-cost model fail to capture the dynamic properties of new exporters? With
fixed entry costs and mean reverting shocks to productivity and the real exchange rate, the
4In the model with stochastic entry cost, 70% of entering plants pay no entry cost and 30% pay an entry cost that is
61% as large as the one in the standard model. See Subsection 6.2 for details.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT