MONEY TALKS? AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF CHEAP TALK AND BURNED MONEY

Published date01 November 2015
AuthorTheo Offerman,Randolph Sloof,Thomas de Haan
Date01 November 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12141
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 56, No. 4, November 2015
MONEY TALKS? AN EXPERIMENTAL INVESTIGATION OF CHEAP TALK
AND BURNED MONEY
BYTHOMAS DE HAAN,THEO OFFERMAN,AND RANDOLPH SLOOF1
Norwegian School of Economics, Norway; University of Amsterdam, The Netherlands;
University of Amsterdam, The Netherlands
We experimentally study the strategic transmission of information in a setting where both cheap talk and money
can be used. Theoretically, many equilibria exist side by side, in which senders use either costless messages, money,
or both. We find that senders prefer to communicate through costless messages. Only when the interest disalignment
between sender and receiver increases does cheap talk tend to break down and high sender types start burning money
to enhance the credibility of their costless messages. A behavioral model assuming that sellers bear a cost of lying fits
the data best.
1. INTRODUCTION
Many strategic interactions contain a phase where the involved parties exchange privately
held information. In the economics literature, two communication channels have been identified
that allow agents to communicate information in a meaningful way. Crawford and Sobel (1982)
showed how in a situation of partial conflict of interests an informed party may employ costless
messages to transmit private information to an uninformed party. In equilibrium, communica-
tion must go via a vague, imprecise language. The conflict of interests shapes the language and
provides a limit to the extent of information transmission. Spence (1973) addressed the question
of how agents can communicate strategically by burning money. In the context of a job market
signaling game in which employers are uninformed about prospective workers’ productivity
type, he showed how high-type job applicants can credibly separate themselves from lower
types by means of obtaining costly (but useless) education. Thus, a sender can credibly signal
information about his type by employing either cheap talk or costly signaling.
In practice, a combination of the two channels is often used though. Take, for instance,
advertising. One acclaimed role of advertising is to provide information to potential buyers
about a product’s attributes (cf. Nelson, 1970, 1974). Some attributes, like price, are easily
verifiable before the product is bought. As there is little room for misrepresentation, such
search attributes can to a large extent be communicated through cheap-talk messages, that is,
the content of the advertisement. Other attributes, like quality, can only be judged upon buying
and actually using the product. These experience attributes are more easily misrepresented,
and the informational value mainly lies in the amount spent: high-quality firms may distinguish
themselves by spending more on—directly uninformative, or dissipative—advertising then low-
quality firms do (Nelson 1970, 1974; Kihlstrom and Riordan, 1984; Milgrom and Roberts, 1986).
As many goods have both search and experience characteristics (and for each attribute, the
distinction is one of degree), costless and costly signaling may be used at the same time. As
another example, a suitor can always blarney his fiancee by simply saying he loves her, but
Manuscript received November 2012; revised May 2014.
1Our article benefited significantly from the constructive and helpful comments of three anonymous referees and the
coeditor Charles Horioka. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Research Priority Area Behavioral
Economics of the University of Amsterdam. We thank CREED-programmer Jos Theelen for programming the exper-
iment. Please address correspondence to: Randolph Sloof, Roetersstraat 11, 1018 WB Amsterdam, the Netherlands.
Phone: +31 (0)20 525 5241. E-mail: r.sloof@uva.nl.
1385
C
(2015) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1386 DE HAAN,OFFERMAN,AND SLOOF
unless he is morally inclined not to lie, this is a cheap-talk message. The bachelor, however, can
also communicate his commitment through offering personalized gifts that are either costly to
find or costly to purchase. This may explain why many men buy (sometimes very expensive)
gifts for their wives/girlfriends (cf. Camerer, 1988). 2
The availability of two types of communication raises the question of exactly how people mix
between costless and costly signals in transmitting private information. The main purpose of this
article is to explore this question in an experiment. In particular, we investigate how the (simul-
taneous) use of and the interplay between cheap-talk and costly signaling varies with the level
of interest alignment between sender and receiver. Intuitively, one would a priori expect that
senders gain credibility when they support their fine talk with conspicuous expenses on costly
signals, especially when interests become less aligned and cheap talk theoretically loses (much
of) its informative value. One might even conjecture that the availability of more informative,
costly signals renders cheap talk by and large meaningless. At the same time, however, it seems
well conceivable that senders prefer to avoid the use of the costly communication channel in
order to save on (potentially high) signaling costs.
Our experimental setup corresponds to the one explored theoretically by Austen-Smith and
Banks (2000). They augment the canonical model for strategic cheap-talk communication of
Crawford and Sobel (1982) with the possibility that the sender may use costly signals as well. In
particular, besides a cheap-talk message, senders may impose costs on themselves by publicly
burning money.3Although this costly signal is in itself a pure social waste, it provides a very
precise measure of how much a sender is prepared to spend to get his true type recognized.
Austen-Smith and Banks show that the set of equilibria dramatically increases when costly
signals can be used. All original equilibria of the Crawford-Sobel (“cheap talk only”) setup are
preserved, but by using the costly channel, new, more informative equilibria exist side by side.
In fact, there exists a continuum of semipooling equilibria, ranging from a complete pooling
equilibrium to a fully separating one. These equilibria differ profoundly in the use of and the
interaction between money and costless messages to signal information.4
In the presence of multiple equilibria, the exact interplay between money and words becomes
an important empirical question. We address this question head on in the controlled environ-
ment of the lab. In our experiment, we implement the standard uniform-quadratic setting of
the strategic communication game, in which the sender’s type is uniformly distributed and the
players’ preferences are represented by quadratic loss functions. (This setting has been the
working horse for most applications of the Crawford and Sobel, 1982, model.) The sender’s
2As expensive gifts may have a resale value, the true signaling value may lie in the purchase price minus the resale
value. Personalizing the gift through, e.g., an inscription lowers the resale value and thus increases the signaling value.
3In contrast to Spence’s original formulation, in Austen-Smith and Banks (2000), the costs of signaling are inde-
pendent of the state. The aforementioned example of advertising provides a real-world case that arguably fits this
assumption. Indeed, most models on directly uninformative, dissipative advertising assume the costs of advertisements
to be state-independent. For industrial organization applications, see, e.g., Kihlstrom and Riordan (1984), Milgrom and
Roberts (1986), Hertzendorf (1993), Bagwell and Ramey (1994), and Bagwell (2007) for an overview. See, e.g., Prat
(2002a, 2002b) and Potters and Van Winden (1992) for applications in political science, such as political campaigning
and lobbying. Within an organizational context, Gibbons et al. (2013, p. 380) discuss the Austen-Smith and Banks
(2000) model, interpreting money burning in reduced form as “...fighting through red tape and bureaucratic sclerosis.”
4Bagwell and Ramey (1993) theoretically explore the interplay between cheap talk and burning money in a more
specific model of informative advertising. In their model, advertising may provide information that helps buyers with
heterogeneous tastes to match with their preferred products. One group of buyers prefers high-quality, high-priced
goods, whereas another group of buyers has a taste for low-priced, low-quality goods. Optimal coordination requires
that firms identify themselves. Firms may potentially do so through the content of their advertising, but these cheap-talk
claims need not be truthful: Firms may pretend to be of a different type to trick consumers of the claimed type to visit
their store. If the share of consumer types is about equal, firms do not benefit from misrepresenting their type, and
the content of the advertisement is credible. If not, high market share firms must turn to costly advertising to signal
their quality. Under free entry, high market shares follow from high fixed costs. Bagwell and Ramey (1993) therefore
conclude that cheap talk can communicate quality when fixed costs are largely independent of quality, whereas if fixed
costs vary significantly with quality, the higher fixed-cost quality levels need to use dissipative advertising to signal
quality.
MONEY TALKS? 1387
bliss point regarding the receiver’s action is bunits above the bliss point of the receiver, with
bias parameter b>0 representing the level of interest disalignment. Within this setting, we
investigate how subjects use the costless and the costly communication channel to signal their
private information and which of these two channels is most prominent. We focus, in particular,
on the impact of different levels of interest disalignment on the mixture of communication
methods employed. In the experiment, we investigate our conjecture that successful communi-
cation through cheap talk gets harder as the bias bgets larger. This may induce a shift toward
communication through burning money when preferences become less aligned.
We obtain the following main experimental findings: Senders appear to have a strong pref-
erence for costless messages. They predominantly choose to communicate through cheap talk,
and cheap talk appears more informative than the most informative Crawford and Sobel equi-
librium predicts. Only when the level of interest disalignment increases and costless messages
turn out to be insufficiently useful for high types to separate themselves from low(er) types do
sender subjects start to burn increasing amounts of money to get their exaggerated cheap-talk
messages across. The amounts of money involved, however, are well below the levels required
by the costly signaling equilibria (as derived in Austen-Smith and Banks, 2000). Nevertheless,
the induced reaction of receivers indicates that senders actually do gain credibility by backing
up their costless messages with burned money.
Our finding that cheap talk is more informative than standard theory predicts is in line with
previous experimental findings. Studying settings that allow for costless communication only,
Dickhaut et al. (1995), Cai and Wang (2006), S´
anchez-Pag´
es and Vorsatz (2007), and Wang et al.
(2010) find that senders consistently overcommunicate as compared to the most informative
equilibrium in cheap-talk games.5Our results indicate that this finding is not an artifact of
imposed limitations on communication, but continues to hold when subjects are allowed to use
alternative, costly communication channels as well.
A plausible explanation of why senders’ cheap-talk messages are more informative than
the standard model predicts is that senders are lying averse. In a recent contribution, Kartik
(2009) analyzes the original setting of Crawford and Sobel under the assumption that senders
bear a cost of lying. He shows that partial separation by means of messages may then occur
in equilibrium, in line with the experimental findings on cheap-talk games. The Kartik model
is readily extended to the situation where senders may burn money as well (see our Section
2). In that case, even full separation is possible, with low types separating through costless
messages and high types by means of burned money. In our empirical analysis, we verify which
equilibrium model fits our data best. We find that Kartik’s original lying cost model—which does
not include the use of burned money—does so. However, there are some clear signs that our
data have not (yet) reached equilibrium. In particular, the equilibrium models do not explain
the actual use and effectiveness of moderate costly signals when preferences are less aligned.
Our article contributes to a small experimental literature comparing the effectiveness of words
and actions in various applications. Duffy and Feltovich (2002, 2006) compare the effectiveness
of cheap talk and observations of previous round actions of others in three different 2×2 games
(prisoners’ dilemma, stag-hunt, and chicken). They find that, when studied in isolation, either
source of information makes coordination and cooperation more likely. Interestingly, having
both information sources present lowers the likelihood of good outcomes, mainly because the
two information channels may lead to opposing interpretations (i.e., point to different expected
actions of the opponent).6Celen et al. (2010) investigate the role of both predecessor’s advice
about how to play and observation of their actions in a standard social learning game. They
observe that advice is more effective despite the fact that the two forms of communication
are theoretically equally informative. A key difference with these earlier papers is that in our
5In contrast, Brandts and Charness (2003) investigate how senders’ communication about intended play in a complete
information game affects receivers’ reciprocal responses. They find that punishment by the receiver is much more likely
if, for the receiver, unfavorable outcome was reached after a deceptive message.
6In a trust game, Bracht and Feltovich (2009) compare cheap talk and observation of the trustees’ past decision and
find that observation leads to much more cooperation, whereas cheap talk has little effect.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT