MISMATCH IN HUMAN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION

AuthorHuacong Liu,Russell Cooper
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12386
Published date01 August 2019
Date01 August 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 3, August 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12386
MISMATCH IN HUMAN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION
BYRUSSELL COOPER AND HUACONG LIU1
Pennsylvania State University, U.S.A., European University Institute, Italy,and NBER;
University of Hamburg, Germany
This article studies the allocation of heterogeneous agents to levels of educational attainment. The goal is
to understand the magnitudes and sources of mismatch in this assignment, both in theory and in the data. The
article presents evidence of substantial mismatch between ability and educational attainment across 21 OECD
countries, with a main focus on Germany, Italy, Japan, and the United States. Model parameters are estimated
using a simulated method of moments approach. The main empirical finding is that measured mismatch arises
largely from noise in test scores and does not reflect borrowing constraints. Taste shocks play a minor role in
explaining mismatch.
1. INTRODUCTION
As noted by the OECD,
Skill mismatch is one of the main challenges faced by economies. Empirical evidence shows that, in far
too many cases, workers are not well-matched with their current jobs.2
Efficiency requires the matching of high-ability people to appropriate education and eventu-
ally to productive jobs. Inefficiencies can arise along a couple of dimensions. First, the sorting
of individuals to education opportunities may be distorted. Second, frictions in labor markets
may prevent the matching of individuals, distinguished by ability and education, with appropri-
ate jobs.
This article studies the first part of the matching process: the allocation of heterogeneous
agents to levels of educational attainment. To the extent high-ability individuals have low
educational attainment and thus low-skill jobs, these forms of mismatch are related.3As we shall
see in some detail, observed educational outcomes are often at odds with the stark predictions
of assortative matching: that is, mismatch occurs when high-ability agents are not always the
most educated and some low-ability agents have high educational attainment. Our primary goal
is to understand the magnitudes, sources, and consequences of this mismatch, both in theory
and in the data.
Manuscript received April 2016; revised November 2018.
1Comments and suggestions from Jonathan Eaton, Martin Hackmann, Eric Hanushek, Marc Henry, Kala Krishna,
Immo Schott, Jon Willis, and Guozhong Zhu as well as seminar participants at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
The University of Montreal, the Pennsylvania State University, the University of Alberta, and the “Occupational Skills
and the Labor Market” conference sponsored by the ZEW in Mannheim Germany are greatly appreciated. Referees
and the editor, Hanming Fang, provided guidance and suggestions that significantly improved this article. Please address
correspondence to: Russell Cooper, Department of Economics, European University Institute, Villa La Fonte, Via delle
Fontanelle, I-50014 San Domenico di Fiesole (FI), Italy. Phone: +39 3271388903. E-mail: russellcoop@gmail.com.
2This was part of a hot issues discussion by the OECD in March 2016. Source: http://skills.oecd.org/
hotissues/skillsmismatch.html. The importance of skills imbalances remains in the policy focus of the OECD. The
OECD Skills for Jobs Database provides timely information for European countries about skill shortages and surpluses.
See more interactive SKILLS FOR JOBS WEB TOOL at http://www.oecd.org/employment/skills-for-jobs-dataviz.htm
3An example is the famous taxi driver in Singapore with a Ph.D.: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Cai_Mingjie. Is
he undermatched in his job or overmatched in education? Subsection 8.3 returns to this theme and discusses the
contribution of education mismatch to apparent job mismatch.
1291
C
(2019) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1292 COOPER AND LIU
The article presents and analyzes cross-country OECD data. The measure of educational
attainment is dichotomous: (i) below college and (ii) college and above. Programme for the
International Assessment of Adult Competencies (PIAAC) scores, an OECD-coordinated
assessment of adult skills, are used in our analysis as noisy measures of ability for each individual
by country.4The use of these data is key to facilitating a cross-country comparison of the
relationship between ability and educational attainment.5
The empirical analysis starts with an assessment of the relationship between PIAAC scores
and educational attainment across countries. Not surprisingly, the distributions of these scores
conditional on educational attainment overlap: There are individuals with a low level of educa-
tion (no college) but a higher PIAAC score than those with high education (college). This is a
simple, but informative, indicator of undermatch.
Our formal analysis of mismatch estimates the probability an individual obtains higher ed-
ucation given an observed PIAAC score.6Using these estimates, “undermatching” occurs if
the predicted probability of a college education is relatively high but the agent does not have a
college degree. In a similar manner, “overmatching” occurs for individuals with a college degree
but a relatively low predicted probability of attending college. These estimates are obtained
using country-specific regressions. In the United States, for example, the undermatch rate is
5.5%, whereas it rises to nearly 15% in Italy. In Japan, the overmatch rate is almost 11%.
These numbers motivate our analysis. What are the sources of this measured mismatch? Does
it signal inefficiency in the allocation of individuals to education outcomes?
The theoretical framework focuses on the assignment of individuals to education levels. It
allows individuals to differ in a number of dimensions: (i) ability, (ii) tastes, and (iii) wealth. If the
only source of heterogeneity is ability, then the optimal allocation will assign higher ability agents
to higher levels of education. There is no mismatch. Once differences in tastes are present, the
optimal allocation assigns educational attainment based on both ability and tastes so that some
high-ability agents will attain relatively low levels of education. The methodology described
above would indicate mismatch, though the allocation may still be efficient. Differences in wealth
are relevant to the assignment process in a decentralized setting with borrowing restrictions. In
this case, relatively high-ability agents may choose a low level of education simply because of
a binding borrowing constraint. So both variations in tastes and binding borrowing constraints
can induce mismatch. Importantly, the borrowing constraint produces undermatch but, given
the cost of education, no overmatch.
In the model, there is another source of mismatch associated with ability being measured
instead of observed. Individuals make education decisions based upon their true ability. Test
scores, such as the PIAAC assessment, are imperfect indicators of ability. Hence, some agents
may appear to be high ability based upon test outcomes though they choose low educational
attainment based upon their true, relatively low ability. This form of mismatch reflects noise
in the measure of ability. As we shall see, this is an important source of measured mismatch in
the data.
The analysis uses this theoretical framework to identify the sources of measured under- and
overmatching. To do so, the country-specific parameters of the individual choice problems
are estimated using a simulated method of moments approach.7The degrees of over- and
undermatching, the mean education rate, the coefficients from the logistic regression used to
4See http://www.oecd.org/site/piaac/ for a complete description of this “survey of adult skills.” The use of this test in
our analysis as a proxy for ability is explained in detail below.
5Hanushek et al. (2015) use the PIAAC score as a measure of cognitive skills in Mincer wage regressions. It is clear
from that analysis that the PIAAC score is highly correlated with labor market outcomes; it is not simply noise. The
PIAAC score is statistically significant in predicting wages even when schooling is included. We use these results as
moments in our estimation. Section 5 of Hanushek et al. (2015) discusses causal interpretations, particularly reverse
causality whereby individuals with particular high skilled jobs, say obtained as the outcome of a training program,
consequently score higher on the PIAAC test.
6This follows Dillon and Smith (2017b), Smith et al. (2013), and others.
7The parameters estimated include the borrowing constraint of the household, the distributions of ability, taste
shocks, and noise in the test score as well as the returns to education.
MISMATCH IN HUMAN CAPITAL ACCUMULATION 1293
predict education outcomes, and coefficients relating wages to PIAAC scores are computed
for each of the countries.8These moments are used as a basis for the estimation of model
parameters. The estimation allows us to determine the source of mismatch across countries.
This article is clearly related to extensive studies of the effects of borrowing constraints and
educational attainment. The empirical results are mainly based on U.S. data. Using National
Longitudinal Study of Youth 1979 (NLSY79) data, Keane and Wolpin (2001), Cameron and
Heckman (2001), Carneiro and Heckman (2002), and Cameron and Taber (2004) show that,
although cost is a significant barrier to college attendance and completion, and family income
plays little role in college attendance after controlling for individual ability. Johnson (2013)
takes a more direct approach and estimates a dynamic model of education, borrowing, and
work decisions of high school graduates using the NLSY97 data. His findings indicate that
borrowing constraints have a small impact on college attainment. In examining the trends of the
effect of credit constraints on educational attainment, Belley and Lochner (2007) and Lochner
and Monge-Naranjo (2011) find that, conditional on ability and family background, parental
income matters much more for educational attainment for the NLSY97 cohort compared to the
NLSY79 cohort.
Our analysis adds to this literature in three important ways. First, we study a cross section
of countries instead of using U.S. data alone.9For European countries, there are very few
empirical studies analyzing how borrowing constraints affect educational attainment, and none
of them relates to mismatch, perhaps reflecting the relatively low cost of higher education.
Second, there is potentially larger variation in tastes, capital market structures, and educational
outcomes across these countries compared to within a single country. Third, we evaluate the
role of borrowing constraints in a structural model, focusing on the effects of these market
imperfections on mismatch.
There are four main findings in this study. First, there is evidence of substantial mismatch in
our sample, including both overmatching and undermatching.
Second, by country, mismatch reflects noise in the test scores and is not due to imperfect
capital markets or to variations in tastes for education across agents. The estimation of the
model finds no support for the presence of binding borrowing constraints.10 Further, taste
shocks contribute essentially nothing to the fit of the model. Instead, noise in the test score is
enough to generate the observed mismatch in a manner that is consistent with the estimated
dependence of the education decision and compensation on the test score. Matching these latter
moments in the estimation critically disciplines the explanatory power of noise in the test score.
From this overidentification, matching these moments from noise in the test score is nontrivial.
Third, mismatch is not a signal of inefficiency. Our simple model, relying solely on a noisy test
score, does a remarkable job of capturing cross-country variations in education rates, mismatch,
and wage premia. It does so by estimating differences in the distribution of ability, the noise
in test scores, and the return to higher education across countries. None of these sources of
variation signal an inefficiency in the allocation of individuals to educational attainment.
Stated differently, as a direct response to the above OECD quote, the mismatch in educational
attainment itself is not a direct source of inefficiency. A model of individuals, making education
choices based on their ability without borrowing constraints and minimal influence of tastes, is
perfectly consistent with data on educational outcomes, including college rates and measured
8Some of these moments are taken from Hanushek et al. (2015).
9An alternative would be to look at evidence of mismatch over time. Hoxby (2009) provides an analysis of the
changing selectively of colleges within the United States. From that analysis, sorting by test scores appears to have
changed over time, with more elite institutions evidently becoming more selective. Dillon and Smith (2017a) compare
mismatch calculated from the NLSY79 sample with that from the NLSY97 sample and find evidence of a “modest
decline” between the two samples.
10 It is interesting to contrast this with the findings of Keane and Wolpin (2001), who also study the interaction of
borrowing constraints and taste shocks. They state: “Although, as noted, borrowing constraints are estimated to be
severe, in neither of these experiments does relaxing the borrowing constraint have a significant effect on completed
schooling” (p. 1053). We do not even find that borrowing constraints bind.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT