HOW TO DESIGN INFRASTRUCTURE CONTRACTS IN A WARMING WORLD: A CRITICAL APPRAISAL OF PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS*

AuthorDavid Martimort,Stéphane Straub
Published date01 February 2016
Date01 February 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12148
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 1, February 2016
HOW TO DESIGN INFRASTRUCTURE CONTRACTS IN A WARMING WORLD:
A CRITICAL APPRAISAL OF PUBLIC–PRIVATE PARTNERSHIPS
BYDAVID MARTIMORT AND ST´
EPHANE STRAUB 1
Paris School of Economics, EHESS, France; Toulouse School of Economics, ARQADE, IDEI,
and IAST, France
We analyze how long-term uncertainty, for example, regarding future climate conditions, affects the design of
concession contracts and organizational forms in a principal–agent context, with dynamic moral hazard, limited liability,
and irreversibility constraints. The prospect of future, uncertain productivity shocks on the returns on the firm’s effort
creates an option value of delaying efforts, a course that exacerbates agency costs. Contracts and organizational forms
are drafted to control this cost of delegated flexibility. The possibility for the agent to delay investment in response to
uncertainty and irreversibility also elicits preference for unbundling different stages of the project through short-term
contracts. Our analysis is relevant to infrastructure sectors that are sensitive to changing weather conditions and sheds
a pessimistic light on the relevance of public–private partnerships in this context.
1. INTRODUCTION
Climate change raises specific and unprecedented challenges surrounding large investments in
infrastructure. The transport, water, and energy sectors are typically characterized by significant
sunk investments and technological choices that are locked in over several decades. Over such
periods, changing weather conditions are expected, albeit unpredictable. Certainly, the current
scientific uncertainty regarding future climate conditions, potentially coupled with the increasing
likelihood of very large catastrophic events, makes long-term decisions in such sectors quite
a challenge for practitioners.2Climate change might have significant implications for future
investments and maintenance of existing assets in key sectors, which in turn might affect the
nature of upfront investments.
Since they involve long-term contracts that often span twenty or thirty years, the so-called
public–private partnerships (PPPs) are particularly sensitive to climate change hazards. Over
recent years, a number of countries, including the United States and several European and
emerging countries, have increasingly relied on PPPs to respond to their investment needs in
sectors involving long-lived capital stock (LLKS).3Because it entails delegation to the pri-
Manuscript received September 2013; revised October 2014.
1We are extremely grateful to Marianne Fay and Daniel Benitez for initiating this research and providing much
detailed comments on a previous version and to PPIAF for providing financial support. An earlier version of this article
was circulated under the title “How to Design Public–Private Partnerships in a Warming World? (When Infrastructure
Becomes a Really Hot Topic).” We thank Perrin Lefebvre for outstanding research assistance and Antonio Estache,
Philippe Gagnepain, Paul Grout, Elisabetta Iossa, Margaret Leighton, St´
ephane Saussier, and Carine Staropoli for very
detailed discussions and challenging views. Two referees and the editor offered important comments that helped us
to improve exposition. Finally, discussions with seminar and conference participants at Tilburg University, IAE Paris,
Maastricht, and the conferences on “Contracts, Procurement and Public-Private Agreements” in Paris (May 2011), The
Economics of Public–Private Partnerships in IESE Barcelona (April 2012), and the APET Workshop in Brisbane (June
2012) were highly appreciated. All errors remain ours. Please address correspondence to: St´
ephane Straub, Toulouse
School of Economics, Universit´
e Toulouse 1 Capitole, 21 all´
ee de Brienne, Bat. F, 31000 Toulouse, France. E-mail:
stephane.straub@tse-eu.fr.
2Weitzman (2009) and Hallegate (2009).
3See, for instance, the exhaustive evidence and discussion in Engel et al. (2008) and Estache and Iimi (2011) and the
statistics reported by Engel et al. (2013) on the growing importance of PPPs in Europe and in the United States, with a
fivefold increase between 1998–2007 and 2008–2010.
61
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
62 MARTIMORT AND STRAUB
vate sector of key decisions over both the structure of initial investments and the subsequent
management of assets over a long period, this contracting mode has also been viewed as an at-
tractive response to important shortages in public funds. Beyond this public finance motivation,
the efficiency gains of PPPs have also been repeatedly emphasized in contexts in which rela-
tionships between public bodies and the private sector are plagued with agency costs, contract
incompleteness, and transaction costs, as pointed out by a burgeoning body of literature.4
Equipped with a model of long-term contracting tailored to the specificities that climate
change brings to the agency relationship between public bodies and firms, this article aims to
analyze the suitability of the standard PPP model in coping efficiently with climate change-
related uncertainty. In a nutshell, we argue that long-term contracting is plagued with new
agency costs of delegated flexibility that might be better controlled when parties wait until
uncertainty regarding climate conditions becomes verifiable to draft new arrangements. The
possibility for the agent to delay investment in response to uncertainty and irreversibility also
calls for unbundling different stages of the project (say building and maintenance, for instance).
This point thus leads to a rather pessimistic view of the benefit of PPPs and long-term contracting
in that context.
Although we chose to cast our contribution in the context of PPPs and climate change-related
uncertainty, as there is an important theoretical literature using similar modeling tools, and this
is also an area of considerable policy relevance, our results speak more generally to the issue
of long-term contracting relationships in contexts of large future uncertainty. We point in the
literature review below and in the final discussion section to some other areas where our results
may be relevant.
Climate change and infrastructure investment. The current process of anthropogenic climate
change, characterized by large and growing uncertainty of future values of environmental
parameters, will dramatically affect the environment in which long-term economic decisions
are made. Indeed, global scenarios related to climate change make it difficult to pinpoint future
outcomes more precisely than broad probability distributions and to rule out disastrous collapses
(IPCC, 2007).
Growing evidence points to a link between anthropogenic greenhouse gases concentration
and local extreme events, such as heat waves, floods, and precipitation.5However, uncovering
the exact channels and providing precise future projections appear to be beyond current sci-
entific possibilities.6As a result, climate risk assessments for specific businesses such as utility
providers are severely limited by the coarse spatial resolution of climate models and the ensuing
lack of clear understanding of how global climate change translates at the local level (IFC, 2010).
Climate change-related hazards are especially relevant to infrastructure on several fronts.
First, the accelerating rate of climate change implies that long-lived investments will have
to cope with a broader range of climatic conditions during their lifetime. Power plants are
typically built to last for at least 30 to 40 years and energy distribution networks and water
and transportation infrastructures for 30 to 100 years.7Such assets are thus likely to experience
large variations in average temperature conditions, precipitation, etc., over their life cycles.
This issue is particularly acute for developing countries, where there are both important needs
for infrastructure investment and wide expectation that the impact of climate change will be
stronger (World Development Report, 2010).
Second, the very nature of infrastructure investments implies crucial sensitivity to climate
hazards. Water collection and distribution networks as well as hydroelectric power plants8are
4Benz et al. (2001), Bennet and Iossa (2006), Hart (2003), Iossa and Martimort (2015), Martimort and Pouyet (2008),
Engel et al. (2010), among many others.
5See Stott et al. (2004), Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan (2009), Pall et al. (2011), and Min et al. (2011).
6Stone and Allen (2005), Piao et al. (2010).
7Shalizi and Lecocq (2009), Hallegate (2009).
8See the case of the Brazilian Belo Monte dam, world’s third largest projected dam. http://www.globalpost.com/
dispatch/brazil/110203/drought-belo-monte-dam, last consulted February 23, 2011.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT