How does Family Control Influence Firm Strategy and Performance? A Meta‐Analysis of US Publicly Listed Firms

AuthorPursey P. M. A. R. Heugens,Michael Carney,Marc Essen,Eric R. Gedajlovic
Published date01 January 2015
Date01 January 2015
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/corg.12080
How does Family Control Influence Firm
Strategy and Performance? A Meta-Analysis of
US Publicly Listed Firms
Marc van Essen*, Michael Carney, Eric R. Gedajlovic, and
Pursey P. M. A. R. Heugens
ABSTRACT
Manuscript Type: Empirical
Research Question/Issue: A contentious and prominent research question in the managementliterature is whether publicly
listed family firms (FFs) outperform other types of corporations. Through a research synthesis of all available studies on the
performance of US FFs, we address this question directly. We also extend the debate by raising three salient follow-up
questions. First, is the performance differential between FFs and non-FFs attributable to a unique set of strategic choices?
Second, do FF performance effects persist across generational transitions in FF control? Third, are performance differentials
across generations attributable to intergenerational shifts in corporate governance and strategy?
Research Findings/Insights: With respect to our primary research question, we find that the balance of evidence indicates
that (US) FFs outperform other types of public corporations. We also evaluate competing narratives regarding which
strategies are characteristic of FFs, and demonstrate that their diversification, internationalization, and financing strategies
mediate the FF-performance relationship in manners consistent with the narratives advanced by certain leading FF scholars,
but not others. Further, we find that the performance of (US) FFs drops dramatically after the first generation and show that
this negative performance differential is due to the much more conservative patterns of strategic decision making enacted
by successor generations.
Theoretical/Academic Implications: In addition to providing the most comprehensive evidence to date regarding the
performance attributes of FFs, we nuance several theoretical debates concerning the propensity of FFs to diversify, inter-
nationalize, and leverage their equity capital.
Practitioner/Policy Implications: We identify value-creating strategic choices of FFs related to internationalization, diver-
sification, and capital structure. We also identify strategic choices often made in successor-led FFs which reduce value. Both
sets of findings are relevant to FF executives and consultants. The policy implications of the study are that in advanced
liberal market economies high-quality capital market institutions are likely to contribute to FF outperformance vis-à-vis
other types of publicly listed firms, but these findings may not hold in other types of national governance systems or in
emerging markets.
Keywords: Corporate Governance, Family Firms, Performance, Generation, Meta-Analysis
INTRODUCTION
Alfred Chandler (1977) famously characterizedthe US as
the seedbed of managerial capitalism. In Chandler’s
view, a professionally managed firm accountable to external
capital markets represents a preeminent and modern
organizational form and one that is best able to compete
successfully in technologically advanced market economies.
In documenting the emergence and domination in the US of
the managerial enterprise and the concomitantdecline of the
“traditional family firm as the primary instrument for man-
aging production and distribution” (1977: 1), Chandler
established a lasting narrative in the management literature,
namely: that in advanced market economies, family firms
(FFs) are plagued by managerial inefficiencies that compro-
mise their competitive capabilities.
*Address for correspondence: Marc van Essen,Darla Moore School of Business, Uni-
versity of South Carolina, Columbia, SC 29208, USA. Tel: 803777-5669; E-mail:
marc.vanessen@moore.sc.edu
3
Corporate Governance: An International Review, 2015, 23(1): 3–24
© 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
doi:10.1111/corg.12080
Yet, while Chandler was confidently proclaiming the
demise of the FF, his contemporaries Jensen and Meckling
(1976) produced a scathing critique of managerial enterprise.
Their agency-theoretic analysis, which identified profes-
sional managers’ self-serving behaviors as a source of
principal-agency costs, still constitutes the dominant theo-
retical paradigm in the mainstream corporate governance
literature. Interestingly, Jensen and Meckling (1976) believed
that owner-managers, typical of family firms, could mitigate
many of the agency problems of the managerial firm due to
their monitoring capacity and their high-powered incentives
to maximize firm value. In so doing, Jensen and Meckling’s
(1976) agency theory launched a potent counter-narrative to
the Chandlerian position that has also become central to the
analysis of effective corporate governance in FFs (Raelin &
Bondy, 2013).
Contrary to Chandler’s prediction, FFs have not disap-
peared from the ranks of leading publicly listed US firms
(Miller, Le Breton-Miller, Lester, & Cannella, 2007), but after
four decades of research on the relative efficiency of mana-
gerially and family controlled firms, the polarized narratives
articulated by Chandler and Jensen and Meckling are not yet
settled. Scholars argue that FF research remains in a pre-
paradigmatic state that is cluttered by conflicting theories
and findings, as well as by significant open questions
regarding the characteristic strategies and performance attri-
butes of FFs (Schulze & Gedajlovic, 2010). On no point is the
field more conflicted than over the question whether FFs
outperform other types of organizations, and Le
Breton-Miller, Miller, and Lester (2011: 704) characterize the
field as bifurcated into “two contradictory family business
perspectives.” Indeed, much of the subsequent theoretical
literature on FFs’ advantages and disadvantages can be read
as a debate, gathering into two opposing camps, fueled by
Chandler’s and Jensen and Meckling’s competing
narratives.
Recent research gathering in the Chandlerian camp holds
that FF inefficiencies arise from conflict between controlling
and minority shareholders (Claessens, Djankov, Fan, &
Lang, 2002), from value-destroying tensions within the con-
trolling family and between family and non-family employ-
ees (Schulze, Lubatkin, Dino, & Buchholtz, 2001), and the
excessive valuation given to socio-emotional wealth by
family members (Gómez-Mejía, Cruz, Berrone, & De Castro,
2011a). These recent perspectives portray FFs as relatively
inefficient organizations that survivein niche markets where
they face little competition. Set against these arguments are
the theoretical perspectives reflecting the positive agency
theory narrative, which suggest that FFs outperform public
corporations operated by salaried executives, due to various
inefficiencies in the latter that are attributable to the separa-
tion of ownership and control (Jensen & Meckling, 1976).
More recent expressions of this perspective suggest that FFs
themselves benefit from the relative advantages of favorable
stakeholder management (Miller, Le Breton-Miller, &
Scholnick, 2008) or capacities for developing certain rent-
generating capabilities (Sirmon & Hitt, 2003). Thus, contro-
versy continues to surround the question as to which of
these views is supported by the body of empirical evidence.
In a departure from research that focuses upon the inter-
nal dynamics of the FF, new comparative research has
begun to address the problem of mixed findings by incor-
porating institutional theory. Potential insights from insti-
tutional theory lay in the possibility that the relative
efficiency of FFs may be attributable to factors external to
the firm, such as the quality of the legal environment, pro-
tection for property rights, and the availability of external
finance (Gedajlovic et al., 2012; Van Essen, Heugens, Van
Oosterhout, & Otten, 2012). One institutional perspective
based on the logic of institutional complementarity sug-
gests that in advanced market economies high-quality insti-
tutions can mitigate the negative tendencies often ascribed
to FFs (García-Castro, Aguilera, & Ariño, 2013; Yoshikawa,
Zhu, & Wang, 2014). Complementarity exists if the pres-
ence or efficiency of an institution increases the returns to
a particular organizational practice or strategy (Hall &
Soskice, 2001). One study pointing to institutional comple-
mentarity concludes that “in well-regulated and transpar-
ent markets, family ownership in public firms reduces
agency problems without leading to severe losses in
decision-making efficiency” (Anderson & Reeb, 2003b:
680). Hence, the logic of institutional complementarity sug-
gests that FF efficiency can be attained through the inter-
action and alignment of external and internal governance
mechanisms. Specifically, public FFs perform well when (i)
large blockholding family members have strong incentives
to monitor professional executives, and (ii) the existence of
transparent and liquid capital markets assures effective
monitoring of family owners.
In marked contrast, there is also an institutional perspec-
tive based upon the logic of institutional substitutability,
which suggests that FF attributes such as a reputation for
honesty (Gilson, 2007) can compensate for under-developed
institutions or “institutional voids” (Miller, Lee, Chang, &
Le Breton-Miller, 2009). Institutional substitutability exists if
the absence or inefficiency of an institution (i.e., an institu-
tional void) increases the returns of a particular organiza-
tional practice or strategy (Hall & Soskice, 2001). In this
view, FFs’ attributes allow them to substitute for missing
institutions, such as inefficient legal processes and insuffi-
cient sources of external finance – conditions common to
emerging and less developed economies. Hence, the analy-
sis of FF performance under conditions of weak institutional
development is based on very different theoretical precepts
than those applied in more advanced economic settings, and
extends beyond the scope of the hypotheses we develop and
test in this paper.
Thus, based on the assumption of complementarity,
focusing upon the performance of publicly listed FFs rela-
tive to other publicly listed firms in the US, a characteris-
tically advanced economy with well-developed
institutions, the performance differences that arise between
firms operating in this context are explained by their inter-
nal dynamics reflecting their corporate governance and
strategic choices. To test hypotheses based upon the com-
peting narratives, we use Hedges and Olkin-type meta-
analytical techniques (HOMA: Hedges & Olkin, 1985) to
synthesize data from multiple studies and bring it to bear
on the open question of whether FFs outperform other
types of business enterprise. In contrast with a recent meta-
analysis using a similar methodology synthesizing interna-
tional studies of unlisted private FFs (Carney, Van Essen,
4CORPORATE GOVERNANCE
Volume 23 Number 1 January 2015 © 2014 John Wiley & Sons Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT