HOUSING DECISION WITH DIVORCE RISK

AuthorMarcel Fischer,Natalia Khorunzhina
Published date01 August 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12385
Date01 August 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 3, August 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12385
HOUSING DECISION WITH DIVORCE RISK
BYMARCEL FISCHER AND NATALIA KHORUNZHINA1
University of Konstanz, Germany, Copenhagen Business School,Denmark; Copenhagen
Business School, Denmark
We build a life-cycle model of housing decisions under divorce risk that predicts that the recent increase in
divorcerates leads to reduced homeownership rates. The risk of a divorce triggers a precautionary-savings motive.
However, this motive is weaker when individuals can invest in owner-occupied homes because homeowners’
higher savings partially substitute for precautionary savings. When young, the larger asset accumulation due
to divorce-risk-induced precautionary savings enables households to buy homes earlier, whereas the presence
of transaction costs leads to reduced homeownership for middle-aged and older households when divorce risk
goes up.
1. INTRODUCTION
Since the 1970s, the share of the divorced population in the United States has been on the
rise, leveling off during the 1990s, and remaining at a high level during the 2000s. According to
the U.S. Census Bureau, in 1970, only 6% of women aged 15 years and above were divorced or
separated, whereas by 2000, their share more than doubled, reaching 13% (Fields and Casper,
2001). Over the same period, homeownership rates declined for the working-age cohorts of
the population (Fisher and Gervais, 2011; Goodman et al., 2015). Owner-occupied homes can
be viewed as a consumption commitment that involves substantial transaction costs at trading
(Chetty and Szeidl, 2007). As the risk of divorce increases, households may be reluctant to
expose themselves to the prospect of an untimely sale of their marital home and shy away from
homeownership. A negative correlation between homeownership and divorce rates observed in
the data is suggestive of this reluctance. An owner-occupied home is the largest single financial
asset for the majority of households. Nevertheless, the implications of divorce risk for housing
and homeownership have received little attention in the literature. In this article, we investigate
the impact of divorce risk on housing decisions of households.
To investigate the mechanism of divorce risk on housing, we construct a life-cycle model of
consumption, investment, and housing decisions, and calibrate it to micro- and macroevidence.
Our model shows that an increase in divorce rates can explain the reduction in homeownership,
Manuscript received April 2016; revised November 2018.
1We would like to thank Mario Crucini, Moira Daly, Marco Della Seta, James Feigenbaum, Grey Gordon, Nadia
Greenhalgh-Stanley, Fane Naja Groes, Georgi Kocharkov, Weicheng Lian, David Love, Jimmy Martinez Correa, Mas-
simo Massa, Dominik Menno, Alvaro Mezza, Robert Miller, Alvin Murphy, Andrey Pavlov, Mauricio Prado, Jesper
Rangvid, Holger Sieg, Steffen Sebastian, Ramona Westermann, and seminar participants at Copenhagen Business
School, the Universities of Aachen, Dortmund, Hannover, Konstanz, and Regensburg, as well as the Midwest Macro
Meeting, the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association Meeting, the Arne Ryde Workshop at Lund
University, the IREBS Conference, the SGF Conference, the ECD Conference, the ReCapNet Conference, the Christ-
mas Meeting of German Economists abroad, and the German Finance Association Annual Meeting for discussions and
insightful comments. We thank Dirk Krueger (the associate editor) and three anonymous referees for their comments,
which helped us improve the article. Marcel Fischer gratefully acknowledges financial support from the Household
Economics and Finance research initiative at Copenhagen Business School and German Research Association (DFG),
grant FI2141/1-1. All errors are our own. Please address correspondence to: Natalia Khorunzhina, Department of
Economics, Copenhagen Business School, Porcelaenshaven 16 A, DK-2000 Frederiksberg, Denmark (DK). Phone:
+45 3815 2403, Fax: +45 3815 2576. E-mail: nk.eco@cbs.dk
1263
C
(2019) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1264 FISCHER AND KHORUNZHINA
observed in the data. Our model predicts that the event of a divorce leads to a long-lasting
reduction in homeownership rates. The risk of divorce triggers a precautionary-savings motive
and results in higher net worth, which can speed up the transition to homeownership. The
precautionary savings channel can be counteracted by the reluctance to incur sizable transaction
costs associated with trading homes when the sale of the marital home is inevitable at divorce.
We find that under the risk of divorce, precautionary savings enable young households to
buy homes earlier, whereas the forfeiture of transaction costs upon divorce results in lower
homeownership rates for middle-aged and older households.
In our model, gender, marital status, and the number and ages of children characterize the
family structure of households. We distinguish between single and married households and allow
households’ marital status to change over time. During their fecund period, females can give
birth to children. Homeownership is strongly desired by households with children ( ¨
Ost, 2012),
which our model addresses by allowing households with children to have a greater preference
for living in an owner-occupied home. In the spirit of Cubeddu and R`
ıos-Rull (2003), marital
status and fertility are treated as shocks, which are conditional on gender, age, and education.
Fertility further depends on marital status, whereas divorce depends on the presence of children
in the household. Mortality rates determine the transition to widowhood and out of population
through death. Our comprehensive treatment of transitions in family structure is an extension
of life-cycle models with housing of Cocco (2005) and Yao and Zhang (2005). Another study
related to our model is Love (2010), who focuses on how family structure affects savings and
asset allocation, but abstracts away from housing decisions.
Households live in an environment of uncertain formation of economic resources, such as
risky returns on real estate and uninsurable income risk. As in Cocco (2005), shocks to labor
income and house prices are positively correlated. Married individuals are subject to lower
income volatility and are therefore less sensitive to unfavorable income shocks. Lower income
risk for married households combined with its positive correlation with house-price risk makes
homeownership less risky for married households and hence more attractive.2Economies of
scale enable married couples to save faster and buy homes earlier.
Our model predicts that divorces decrease the demand for homeownership. This finding is
consistent with the empirical analysis that we conduct using various data and different levels
of aggregation from individual to aggregated regional data. In our model, the drop in home-
ownership is mainly driven by three effects. First, divorce instantly implies a sharp drop in
household net worth due to the splitting of assets and the cost of divorce. Second, the newly
divorced individual cannot take full advantage of the economies of scale. Third, the new single’s
income is subject to a higher volatility than the former couple’s. Higher income risk for divorced
households combined with its correlation with house-price risk makes homeownership riskier
for divorced households, and hence less attractive.
Cubeddu and R`
ıos-Rull (2003), Fern´
andez and Wong (2014), and Voena (2015) show that
higher divorce risk results in increased savings for married couples. Likewise, we find that
divorce risk triggers the precautionary-savings motive. When divorce risk is high, individuals
save more to smooth the possible transition to a less economically favorable post-divorce state.
We compare net worth accumulation in a model with owner-occupied homes to net worth
accumulation in a model without homeownership, and we draw two conclusions. First, the dual
role of owner-occupied homes as both consumption and investment goods makes investment
in owner-occupied homes attractive and leads to generally higher levels of net worth than for
households that cannot acquire owner-occupied homes. Second, the opportunity to invest in
owner-occupied homes weakens the precautionary-savings motive, because the higher savings
of homeowners substitute for precautionary savings.
2Bertocchi et al. (2011), considering marriage as a sort of safe asset, show that married individuals have a higher
propensity to invest in risky assets. Similarly, risky housing in our model is more attractive to married households
because of the implicit spousal insurance, resulting in lower income risk.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT