Gradualism in the GATT: Strategic tariff bargaining and forward manipulation

AuthorJackie M. L. Chan
Date01 February 2019
Published date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12373
220
|
© 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:220–239.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
In the decades following the formation of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
in 1947, countries negotiated for the mutual reduction of trade barriers in organized trade
rounds. In the first five trade rounds (Geneva [1947], Annecy [1949], Torquay [1950–1951],
Geneva [1955–1956], and Dillon [1960–1961]), negotiations for import tariffs were made on
an item‐by‐item offer‐request basis. With multiple trading partners involved, these negotiations
proceeded sequentially and bilaterally under the most‐favored-nation (MFN) principle (i.e.,
GATT/WTO Article I). Under such conditions, countries would have a strong motive for stra-
tegic tariff bargaining to influence the outcomes of the agreement. Indeed, as once remarked
by John Evans, a former member of the U.S. delegation to the GATT: “If a round of negoti-
ations is to be followed by later rounds, one’s own tariff level takes on a value independent
of any economic reason for protection. Quite simply, it has value as bargaining counter in fu-
ture rounds” (Roessler, 1978). In particular, this suggests that early participants may have an
incentive to engage in inefficient “foot‐dragging”, and offer fewer concessions to earlier
Received: 16 January 2017
|
Revised: 16 May 2018
|
Accepted: 15 June 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12373
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Gradualism in the GATT: Strategic tariff
bargaining and forward manipulation
Jackie M. L. Chan
Department of Economics,Chinese
University of Hong Kong, Shatin, Hong
Kong
Correspondence
Jackie M. L. Chan, Department of
Economics, 9/F, Esther Lee Building,
Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin,
N.T., Hong Kong.
Email: jmlchan@cuhk.edu.hk
Abstract
This paper examines strategic bargaining in a non‐coop-
erative game of tariff negotiation in the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). In the model, a country bar-
gains sequentially and bilaterally with multiple trading
partners under the MFN principle, making take‐it‐or‐
leave‐it offers consisting of tariffs and transfers. A dy-
namic bargaining inefficiency arises in which the country
strategically delays the reduction of its tariff until the final
stage, and extensions to the model demonstrate gradual
trade liberalization over multiple stages. Based on this
idea of forward manipulation, the theory provides an ex-
planation for gradualism in tariff reduction during the
early GATT rounds.
|
221
CHAN
negotiating partners in order to maintain a more favorable bargaining position for future negotia-
tions (Bagwell & Staiger, 2010; WTO, 2007). This incentive has been formally characterized by
Bagwell and Staiger (2010) as “forward manipulation”, in which early agreements are manipu-
lated to affect the outcomes of later negotiations.
In this paper, I argue that the forward‐manipulation problem provides an explanation for grad-
ualism in trade liberalization during the early GATT rounds. Aside from the initial Geneva (1947)
Round, the four subsequent trade rounds that relied on the item‐by‐item bargaining method did not
result in major tariff reductions (Hoekman & Kostecki, 2009, p. 136; Irwin, 1995a, 1995b). In fact,
negotiations from the Annecy to Dillon Rounds produced a cumulative reduction in tariff levels of
only 14% (WTO, 2007, Table 5). In contrast, with the adoption of across‐the‐board formulas to cut
tariffs, the Kennedy (1963–1967) and Tokyo (1973–1979) Rounds achieved reductions of 38 percent
and 33 percent, respectively. Moreover, compared with the 33,000 tariff lines bound in the Kennedy
Round, each of the four rounds after the Geneva (1947) Round had less than 10,000 tariff concessions
exchanged, with as few as 4,400 in the Dillon Round. As Cohn (2002, p. 59) states, “the method of
negotiation was the most important factor hindering the achievement of more positive results.” In
particular, across the rounds, “foot‐dragging by any important country could slow everyone’s negoti-
ations” (Diebold, 1996, p. 159).
With a stylized model of sequential bilateral bargaining in the GATT, I demonstrate the forward‐
manipulation problem and how it could lead to gradualism in tariff reduction. The basic three‐coun-
try theoretical framework mainly follows Bagwell and Staiger (2010) and Kungpanidchakul (2007),
where Country A exports to and imports from Countries B and C.1 Country A also negotiates se-
quentially and bilaterally under MFN with B and C.2 In each stage of this non‐cooperative bargaining
game, Country A makes a take‐it‐or‐leave‐it (TOL) offer consisting of its own tariff, either B or C’s
tariff levied on A’s exports, and a lump‐sum transfer payment from A to B or C. The use of transfer
payments ensures that the model is analytically tractable. While monetary transfers between GATT
contracting parties were not observed, these side‐payments can be interpreted more generally as con-
cessions on other instruments of trade policy. This includes reductions in non‐tariff barriers through
issue linkage, which has also been important in GATT trade negotiations (Bagwell & Staiger, 2010;
Hoekman & Kostecki, 2009, p. 154).
As first‐movers of this game in Stage 1, Countries A and B have an incentive to manipulate C’s
disagreement payoff, pushing C into a weaker bargaining position, thereby extracting more surplus. If
Country C rejects A’s Stage 2 offer, its disagreement payoff or outside option will depend on the Stage
1 tariffs negotiated between A and B, which remains in effect because of MFN. Thus, the dynamic
inefficiency of forward manipulation arises in which Country A preserves its bargaining chips for
Stage 2 by strategically delaying the reduction of its MFN tariff. To achieve this outcome, Country
A demands tariff concessions from B in Stage 1, and offers alternative concessions in the form of
transfers. This result also holds in alternative setups with more than three countries, size asymmetry,
and differences in bargaining power.
To generate gradual trade liberalization in which tariff reduction is observed over all stages, I
extend the basic model in three directions. First, I introduce a time lag between the two stages, so
that consumption and welfare depend on both Stage 1 and 2 tariffs. While the forward‐manipulation
incentive remains, it is mitigated by the force that drives tariffs down in Stage 2, namely, the trade‐off
between tariff concessions and transfers. Furthermore, this trade‐off is exacerbated when transfers are
limited. By introducing a constraint in which transfers are capped at an upper bound, it can be shown
that Country A must offer additional tariff concessions in Stage 1. Lastly, gradualism also arises
when the probability of negotiation breakdown is large. Again, while Country A is still incentivized

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT