GLOBAL POPULATION GROWTH, TECHNOLOGY, AND MALTHUSIAN CONSTRAINTS: A QUANTITATIVE GROWTH THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE

AuthorSimon Dietz,Bruno Lanz,Timothy Swanson
Date01 August 2017
Published date01 August 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12242
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 3, August 2017
GLOBAL POPULATION GROWTH, TECHNOLOGY, AND MALTHUSIAN
CONSTRAINTS: A QUANTITATIVE GROWTH THEORETIC PERSPECTIVE
BYBRUNO LANZ,SIMON DIETZ,AND TIMOTHY SWANSON1
University of Neuchˆ
atel, Switzerland;London School of Economics and Political Science, U.K.;
Graduate Institute, Switzerland
We structurally estimate a two-sector Schumpeterian growth model with endogenous population and finite
land reserves to study the long-run evolution of global population, technological progress, and the demand
for food. The estimated model closely replicates trajectories for world population, GDP, sectoral productivity
growth, and crop land area from 1960 to 2010. Projections from 2010 onward show a slowdown of technological
progress, and, because it is a key determinant of fertility costs, significant population growth. By 2100, global
population reaches 12.4 billion and agricultural production doubles, but the land constraint does not bind because
of capital investment and technological progress.
1. INTRODUCTION
World population has doubled over the last 50 years and quadrupled over the past century
(United Nations, 1999). During this period and in most parts of the world, productivity gains
in agriculture have confounded Malthusian predictions that population growth would outstrip
food supply. Population and income have determined the demand for food and thus agricultural
production, instead of food availability determining population. However, recent evidence
suggests a widespread slowdown of growth in agricultural output per unit of land area (i.e.,
agricultural yields; see Alston et al., 2009), and the amount of land that can be brought into the
agricultural system is physically finite. For reasons such as these, several prominent contributions
from the natural sciences have recently raised the concern that a much larger world population
cannot be fed (e.g., Godfray et al., 2010; Tilman et al., 2011). Our aim in this article is to study
how population and the demand for land interacted with technological progress over the past
50 years and derive some quantitative implications for the years to come.
Despite the importance of these issues, few economists have contributed to the debate about
the role of Malthusian constraints in future population growth. This is especially surprising given
the success of economic theories in explaining the (past) demographic transition in developed
countries in the context of their wider development paths (e.g., Galor and Weil, 2000; Jones,
2001; Bar and Leukhina, 2010; Jones and Schoonbroodt, 2010, and other contributions reviewed
below). Empirical evidence emphasizes the role of technology, education, and per-capita income
in long-run fertility development (e.g., Rosenzweig, 1990; Herzer et al., 2012), and it documents
a complementarity between technological progress and the demand for human capital (Goldin
and Katz, 1998). Furthermore, per-capita income is an important determinant of the demand
Manuscript received June 2015; revised January 2016.
1We thank Alex Bowen, Julien Daubanes, Derek Eaton, Sam Fankhauser, Timo Goeschl, David Laborde, Guy
Meunier, Antony Millner, Pietro Peretto, John Reilly, Emilson Silva, David Simpson, Simone Valente, and Marty
Weitzman as well as seminar participants at ETH Z¨
urich, INRA-ALISS, LSE, the University of Cape Town, IUCN,
SURED 2014, and Bioecon 2013 for comments and discussions. We are also particularly grateful for the comments and
suggestions made by the associate editor and three anonymous referees. Excellent research assistance was provided
by Ozgun Haznedar and Arun Jacob. The GAMS code for the model is available from Bruno Lanz’s we site. Funding
from the MAVA foundation is gratefully acknowledged. Any remaining errors are ours.
Please address correspondence to: Bruno Lanz, Department of Economics and Business, University of Neuchˆ
atel,
A.-L. Breguet 2, CH-2000 Neuchˆ
atel, Switzerland. E-mail: bruno.lanz@unine.ch.
973
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
974 LANZ,DIETZ,AND SWANSON
for food (e.g., Subramanian and Deaton, 1996; Thomas and Strauss, 1997), just as technological
progress is of food production and associated demand for land (Alston and Pardey, 2014).
The role of economic incentives and technology in the long-run evolution of population and
per capita income and the associated demand for food and land is, however, absent from leading
international assessments of population growth and agricultural production. In addition, while
the evolution of population and agriculture is inherently interconnected, they are considered
separately. On the one hand, the de facto standard source of demographic projections is the
United Nations’ series of World Population Prospects. The UN works from the basic demo-
graphic identity that the change in population, at the global level, is equal to the number of
births less the number of deaths, with exogenous trajectories assumed for fertility and mortality.
Implications for food demand and supply are not explicitly considered, although it is implic-
itly assumed that the projected population can be supported by agricultural production. On
the other hand, agricultural projections by the Food and Agriculture Organisation of the UN
(FAO) use exogenous trajectories for population, per-capita income, and agricultural yields
(see Alexandratos and Bruinsma, 2012). Clearly, considering outcomes separately makes the
assessment of potential Malthusian constraints difficult.
In this article, we propose to use an integrated, quantitative approach to study the interactions
between global population, technological progress, per-capita income, demand for food, and
agricultural land expansion. More specifically, we formulate a model of endogenous growth with
an explicit behavioral representation linking child-rearing decisions to technology, per-capita
income, and availability of food. In the tradition of Barro and Becker (1989), households in
the model have preferences over own consumption, the number of children they have, and
the utility of their children. Child rearing is time intensive, and fertility competes with other
labor-market activities. As in Galor and Weil (2000), technological advances are associated with
a higher demand for human capital, capturing the aforementioned complementarity between
human capital and the level of technology, so that the cost of educating children increases with
technological progress. It follows that, over time, technological process gradually increases the
cost of population increments (or additions to the stock of effective labor units) both directly
(as human capital requirements and education costs increase) and indirectly (as wages and the
opportunity cost of time increases), which induces a gradual transition to a low-fertility regime.
Besides the cost of rearing and educating children, the other key driver of population growth
in our model is food requirements. As in Strulik and Weisdorf (2008), Vollrath (2011), and Sharp
et al. (2012), we make agricultural output a necessary condition to sustain the contemporaneous
level of population. In addition, the demand for food is increasing in per-capita income (albeit at
a declining rate; see Subramanian and Deaton, 1996), reflecting empirical evidence on how diet
changes as affluence rises. An agricultural sector, which meets the demand for food, requires
land as an input, and agricultural land has to be converted from a stock of natural land.
Therefore, as population and income grow, the demand for food increases, raising the demand
for agricultural land. In the model, land is treated as a scarce form of capital, which has to be
converted from a finite together resource stock of natural land. The cost of land conversion
and the fact that it is physically finite together generate a potential Malthusian constraint to
long-run economic development.
In our model, technology plays a central role in both fertility and land conversion decisions.
On the one hand, technological progress raises the opportunity and human-capital cost of
children. On the other hand, whether land conversion acts as a constraint on population growth
mainly depends on technological progress. We model the process of knowledge accumulation
in the Schumpeterian framework of Aghion and Howitt (1992), where the growth rate of total
factor productivity (TFP) increases with labor hired for research and development (R&D)
activities. A well-known drawback of such a representation of technological progress is the
population-scale effect (see Jones, 1995a).2This is important in a setting with endogenous
2The population scale effect, or positive equilibrium relationship between the size of the labor force and aggregate
productivity growth, can be used to explain the take-off phase that followed stagnation in the preindustrial era (e.g.,
GLOBAL POPULATION GROWTH 975
population, as it would imply that accumulating population would increase long-run technology
and income growth. By contrast, our representation of technological progress falls in the class
of Schumpeterian growth models that dispose of the scale effect by considering that innovation
applies to a growing number of differentiated products (“product lines”; see Dinopoulos and
Thompson, 1998; Peretto, 1998; Young, 1998), so that long-run growth is not proportional to
the level or growth rate of population.3
To fix ideas, we start with a simple theoretical illustration of the mechanism underlying fertility
and land conversion decisions in our model. However, the main contribution of our work is
to structurally estimate the model and use it to study the quantitative behavior of the system.
More specifically, most of the parameters of the model are either imposed or calibrated from
external sources, but those determining the marginal cost of population, labor productivity in
sectoral R&D, and labor productivity in agricultural land conversion are structurally estimated
with simulation methods. We use 1960–2010 data on world population, GDP, sectoral TFP
growth, and crop land area to define a minimum distance estimator, which compares observed
trajectories with those simulated from the model. We show that trajectories simulated with
the estimated vector of parameters closely replicate observed data for 1960–2010, and that the
estimated model also provides a good account of nontargeted moments over the estimation
period, notably agricultural output and its share of total output. We then employ the estimated
model to jointly project outcomes up to 2100.
The key results are as follows: Trajectories from the estimated model suggest a population of
9.85 billion by 2050, further growing to 12.4 billion by 2100. Moreover, although the population
growth rate declines over time, population does not reach a steady state over the period we
consider. This is mainly due to the fact that the pace of technological progress, which is the
main driver of the demographic transition in our model, declines over time, so that population
growth remains positive over the horizon we consider. Despite a doubling of agricultural output
associated with growth in population and per-capita income, agricultural land expansion stops
by 2050 at around 1.8 billion hectares, a 10% increase over 2010.4A direct implication of our
work is that the land constraint does not bind, even though (i) our population projections are
higher than UN’s latest (2012) estimates; and (ii) our projections are rather conservative in
terms of technological progress (agricultural TFP growth in both sectors is below 1% per year
and declining from 2010 onward).
One important feature of these dynamics is that they derive entirely from the structure of
the model, instead of changes in the underlying parameters. We also consider the sensitivity
and robustness of our results to a number of assumptions, notably substitution possibilities in
agriculture and the income elasticity of food demand. Overall, we find that projections from
the model are fairly robust to plausible changes in the structure of the model. Some variations
suggest an optimal population path that is higher than our baseline case, although the evolution
of agricultural land is only marginally affected. The robustness of our results essentially derives
from estimating the model with 50 years of data, tying down trajectories over a long time
horizon.
1.1. Related Literature. Our work relates to at least three strands of economic research.
First, there is unified growth theory, which studies economic development and population over
Boserup, 1965; Kremer, 1993). However, empirical evidence from growth in recent history is difficult to reconcile with
the scale effect (e.g., Jones, 1995b; Laincz and Peretto, 2006). See Strulik et al. (2013) on how the transition between
the two growth regimes can be explained endogenously through accumulation of human capital.
3In a product-line representation of technological progress, R&D takes place at the firm (or product) level, and new
firms are allowed to enter the market. An implication is that the number of products grows over time, thereby diluting
R&D inputs, so that growth does not necessarily rely on an increasing labor force assigned to R&D activities, but rather
on the share of labor in the R&D sector (Laincz and Peretto, 2006).
4This corresponds to the conversion of a further 150 million hectares of natural land into agriculture, roughly the area
of Mongolia or three times that of Spain. Because developed countries will likely experience a decline in agricultural
land area (Alexandratos and Bruinsma, 2012), land conversion in developing countries will need to be more than that.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT