EXTREMIST PLATFORMS: POLITICAL CONSEQUENCES OF PROFIT‐SEEKING MEDIA

AuthorJaideep Roy,Kalyan Chatterjee,Siddhartha Bandyopadhyay
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12453
Date01 August 2020
Published date01 August 2020
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 61, No. 3, August 2020 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12453
EXTREMIST PLATFORMS: POLITICAL CONSEQUENCES OF PROFIT-SEEKING
MEDIA
BYSIDDHARTHA BANDYOPADHYAY,KALYAN CHATTERJEE,AND JAIDEEP ROY1
Department of Economics, University of Birmingham, Birmingham B152TT, U.K.; Department
of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16801 U.S.A.; Department of
Economics, University of Bath, Claverton Down, Bath BA27AY,U.K.
We analyze how information about candidate quality affects the choice of electoral platforms made by an
office-motivated political challenger. The incumbent is of known quality and located at the ideal policy of the
voter. The voter cares for both policy and the candidates’ quality and can learn about the challenger’s quality by
buying information. A high-quality challenger then has an incentive to signal her quality by choosing a policy that
induces the voter to buy information. We first study the benchmark case in which the information is supplied
exogenously, and its quality is independent of the challenger’s platform; this yields multiple equilibria and
indeterminacy of equilibrium platforms. By contrast, when the information is supplied by a profit-maximizing
media outlet, its quality depends on the challenger’s platform and we obtain a unique equilibrium platform. In
particular, when the incumbent’s quality is relatively low, the media coverage rises and the challenger’s platform
diverges further from the voter’s ideal policy as the voter’s preference for quality increases.
1. INTRODUCTION
We study how information about the quality of politicians can affect their choice of platforms.
In particular, we analyze whether, and under what conditions, this can cause the rise and electoral
success of politicians who espouse policies that are distinctly positioned to the right or left of the
median voter. While politicians with median platforms are supposed to be more successful by
being closer to a majority of voters, there are examples of politicians (and parties) who have run
for office by taking stands on certain issues that are different from the median platform.2This
has been seen in the success of Narendra Modi in India, of Donald Trump in the United States
and the rise of far right parties across Europe, all occurring at a time of voter dissatisfaction
about politicians in power.3At the same time, there is evidence—for example, from the 2014
Manuscript received July 2017; revised February 2019.
1We are grateful to the editors and an anonymous referee for several comments and suggestions that have helped us
improve the presentation of the article. We also thank Sandro Brusco, Matthew Cole, Kaustav Das, Amrita Dhillon,
Jon Eguia, Matthew Gentzkow, Aditya Goenka, Matt Golder, Indridi Indridason, Navin Kartik, Hongyi Li, Simon
Loertscher, Bryan McCannon, S. Nageeb Ali, Colin Rowat, Kunal Sengupta, Francesco Squintani, Samarth Vaidya and
seminar participants at University of Adelaide, University of Bath, King’s College London, University of Birmingham,
UNSW, University of Melbourne, Jadavpur University, Monash University, Calcutta University, the Indian Statistical
Institute (Kolkata), the SAET 2015 conference in Cambridge, the 2016 NICEP Inaugural Conference in Nottingham
and the 2016 META workshop in Cardiff for comments. Chatterjee wishes to thank the Richard B. Fisher Endowment of
the Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton, NJ, for making his membership of the Institute possible for 2014–15 during
which work on this project was undertaken. We thank Sreeparna Saha and Ritvij Roy for helping us with the diagrams.
Please address correspondence to: Jaideep Roy, Department of Economics, University of Bath, Claverton DriveBath
BA2 7AY, U.K.; Phone: +44 (0) 1225 38 5269. E-mail: J.Roy@bath.ac.uk.
2Following Kartik and McAfee (2007) and the subsequent articles in the literature, in the rest of the article, we shall
refer to candidate platforms that do not coincide with the median voter’s as “extremist.” This is to be understood as a
comparative term; the further the platform from the median voter’s, the more extremist it is.
3See Golder (2016) for a review that analyzes the rise of the far right for Europe. This dissatisfaction was
also seen in the United States where only 33% of voters thought the country is in the right direction (see
1173
C
(2020) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1174 BANDYOPADHYAY,CHATTERJEE,AND ROY
Indian General elections and the 2016 U.S. Presidential elections—of unprecedented media
attention for such candidates.4
There can be many reasons behind media attention for extremist platforms. This article
shows how the presence of a partially revealing signal about candidate quality—for example,
through media coverage— with voter beliefs about quality to determine the politician’s choice
of platform away from the voter’s ideal policy. We study this in a scenario where there is an
incumbent of known quality facing a challenger whose quality is unknown. If the source from
where the information emanates has an incentive to satisfy the voter’s demand for news (e.g., a
profit maximizing media), the challenger will choose a particular policy that moves away from
the voter’s ideal point—thus becoming extremist—as the voter’s preference for a high-quality
challenger increases. To strip out the impact of various competing channels that can also lead to
extremist platforms, we construct a model where neither the media nor the challenger has any
ideological bias and there is only a single voter. Extremist platforms are chosen by candidates
because the demand for information about a relatively unknown challenger increases with both
the distance between the platform from the voter’s ideal policy and with higher quality of
information. Voters face a higher cost of making a wrong choice when electing a candidate
who makes policy commitments that are away from the median. This generates demand for
information that a high-quality challenger exploits, aided by the media outlet responding to its
profit-seeking interests by providing enhanced coverage for such a candidate.
We now explain the mechanism in more detail. The voter in our model cares about two
dimensions, a horizontal dimension which we interpret as policy and a vertical dimension which
we call quality. The voter has a bliss point on the policy dimension while utility is monotonic
on the quality dimension. There is an unknown challenger facing a known incumbent in a
winner take all election. The challenger knows his or her quality while other participants hold
a common prior belief on this quality. The challenger incurs a cost to enter the race against
the incumbent. There is a media outlet that is willing to provide the voter a signal about the
challenger if the voter pays a fee.5The signal reveals the true quality of the challenger with some
probability. This probability is increasing in the level of (costly) investment made by the media
outlet. This induces candidates of high-quality, who want more media coverage, to rationally
take a policy position away from the voter, generating voter demand for information. The voter
of course has a choice of whether or not to buy information from the media outlet. In a situation
where the voter is not particularly happy with the incumbent, he would like to consider voting
for the challenger. However, if the challenger takes a relatively extreme position (compared to
the voter’s bliss point) the cost of choosing the winner incorrectly is greater for the voter. This
increased value for information increases the voter’s demand for news and the media outlet, in
anticipation, invests more in coverage of a more extreme candidate.
The assumption of profit-maximizing behavior of the media outlet is consistent with the
findings by Genztkow and Shapiro (2010) that the slant that a newspaper chooses are on
average close to what it would have chosen if it had “independently maximized its own profits.”
In addition, our observation on media coverage of candidates with platforms away from the
median is consistent with empirical evidence from the United States and some stylized facts
across the world. McCluskey and Kim (2012) examined the coverage of 208 political action
groups in 118 newspapers in the United States. They conclude that “groups that expressed
more polarized opinions on political issues were mentioned in larger newspapers, appeared
http://www.rasmussenreports.com/public-content/politics/mood-of-america/right-direction-or-wrong-track). Even
when they did not win, far left politicians like Bernie Sanders in the United States as well as Jeremy Corbyn in the
United Kingdom have been far more popular electorally than anticipated.
4A recent article by Frank Bruni at the New York Times entitled, “Will the media be Trump’s accomplice again in
2020” highlights this.
5Subscription fees are widespread for better known outlets like the New York Times or The Times. However it is
important to understand that our results remain intact if instead we assume that the voter must incur some cost in
following the media, while media revenues are generated through commercial adverts that respond positively to the
size of viewership.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT