EXTREME EVENTS AND OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

AuthorFrancisco Ruge‐Murcia,Jinill Kim
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12372
Date01 May 2019
Published date01 May 2019
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 60, No. 2, May 2019 DOI: 10.1111/iere.12372
EXTREME EVENTS AND OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY
BYJINILL KIM AND FRANCISCO RUGE-MURCIA1
Korea University, Korea; McGill University, Canada
This article studies the implication of extreme shocks for monetary policy. The analysis is based on a small-
scale New Keynesian model with sticky prices and wages where shocks are drawn from asymmetric generalized
extreme value distributions. A nonlinear perturbation solution of the model is estimated by the simulated method
of moments. Under the Ramsey policy, the central bank responds nonlinearly and asymmetrically to shocks.
The trade-off between targeting a gross inflation rate above 1 as insurance against extreme shocks and targeting
an average gross inflation at unity to avoid adjustment costs is unambiguously decided in favor of strict price
stability.
1. INTRODUCTION
Economies are occasionally subjected to extreme shocks that can have profound and long-
lasting effects—think, for example, of the oil shocks in the 1970s or the financial shocks associ-
ated with the Great Recession. Thus, it is important to design policy by taking into account the
fact that extreme events can happen sometimes. This article studies the positive and normative
implications of extreme shocks for monetary policy using a small-scale New Keynesian model
with sticky prices and sticky—and more downwardly rigid—wages (see Kim and Ruge-Murcia,
2009). Crucially, the model relaxes the usual assumption that shocks are normally distributed
and assumes instead that they are drawn from asymmetric distributions with an arbitrarily long
tail. Methodologically, we use tools from extreme value theory, which is a branch of statistics
concerned with extreme deviations from the median of probability distributions. This theory
was developed primarily in meteorology and engineering, where designers are interested in
protecting structures against infrequent—but potentially damaging—events like earthquakes
and hurricanes.2
Previous research on the positive analysis of monetary policy typically works under the dual
assumptions that the propagation mechanism is linear and that shocks are symmetric, usually
normal. In some normative analysis, it is necessary to go beyond a linear approximation of
the model dynamics to avoid spurious welfare implications, and a second-order approximation
is consistent with any two-parameter distribution. Since the normal distribution satisfies this
two-degrees-of-freedom specification, the normal distribution is also widely used in normative
analysis. This strategy leads to tractable models, but, as we argue below, it is unsatisfactory for
understanding policy responses to extreme events.
Instead, the shock innovations in our model are assumed to be drawn from generalized
extreme value (GEV) distributions. This distribution is widely used in extreme value theory to
Manuscript received June 2018; revised August 2018.
1This article was previously circulated under the title “Extreme Events and the Fed.” The authors benefitted from
comments by Luigi Boccola, Marcelle Chauvet, the editor (J. Fern´
andez-Villaverde), and two anonymous referees.
Ruge-Murcia acknowledges the support from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council (SSHRC), and
from the Bank of Canada through its Fellowship Program. Kim’s work was supported by a grant from Korea Uni-
versity (K1808651). Please address correspondence to: Francisco Ruge-Murcia, Department of Economics, McGill
University, 855 Sherbrooke Street West, Montreal, Quebec H3A 2T7, Canada (CA). Phone: +1 (514) 398 6063. E-mail:
francisco.ruge-murcia@mcgill.ca.
2Key contributions in extreme value theory are Fisher and Tippett (1928), Gnedenko (1943), and Jenkinson (1955).
For a review of applications in engineering, meteorology, and insurance, see Coles (2001) and Embrechts et al. (2011).
939
C
(2018) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
940 KIM AND RUGE-MURCIA
model the maxima (or minima) of a sequence of random variables.3The distribution has three
independent parameters that determine its first, second, and third moments. To be consistent
with considering three moments of the distribution, we approximate the model dynamics using a
third-order perturbation, and so our approximate solution is nonlinear. The nonlinear model is
estimated by the simulated method of moments (SMM). To disentangle the relative contribution
of asymmetric shocks and nonlinearity to our results, we also estimate a nonlinear version of
the model with normal innovations. Results show that the data prefer a specification where
monetary policy innovations are drawn from a positively skewed distribution, and productivity
and preference innovations are drawn from negatively skewed distributions. This conclusion is
based on structural estimates from the model and also supported by reduced-form estimates
from the raw data.
Using the estimated parameters, we examine the normative implications of the model under
the Ramsey policy. We find that the benevolent monetary authority responds asymmetrically
to shocks, and the change in the nominal interest rate is generally larger than that under
the Taylor policy. In addition to investigating the optimal monetary policy response to large
shocks, this article derives specific policy prescriptions concerning optimal inflation targets.
This issue is important because, in light of the recent Global Financial Crisis, Williams (2009,
2014), Blanchard et al. (2010), and Ball (2014) propose increasing inflation targets in order to
provide a larger buffer zone from the zero lower bound (ZLB) on interest rates. In one of the
few contributions to the literature on optimal policy in an environment with extreme shocks,
Svensson (2003) notes the tension between (i) acting prudently and incorporating systematically
the possibility of extreme shocks into policy (e.g., by raising the inflation target) and (ii) taking
a wait-and-see approach. Under the wait-and-see approach, the monetary authority acts only if
and when an extreme shock occurs and adjusts the policy variables appropriately to counteract
its effects. Our model incorporates such a trade-off and uses quantitative analysis to compare
these two strategies using a well-defined welfare metric. We show that the solution to the trade-
off is solved unambiguously in favor of the wait-and-see approach. The reason is simply that,
although prudence calls for an optimal gross inflation target above 1 as an insurance against
extreme shocks that would require costly nominal wage cuts, such a target involves price-and-
wage adjustment costs that must paid in every period. Thus, under the Ramsey policy the
optimal gross inflation rate is virtually indifferent from 1 (i.e., strict price stability).
The New Keynesian model used to study extreme shocks is based on our previous work (Kim
and Ruge-Murcia, 2009). We use this model for two reasons. First, this model is highly nonlinear
because of the asymmetry in wage adjustment costs. Nonlinearity is a key ingredient in evalu-
ating the economic implications of extreme shocks because it can give rise to prudent behavior.
Second, this model has a well-defined cost of deflation in the form of very costly nominal wage
cuts.4However, this project makes a distinct contribution from Kim and Ruge-Murcia (2009).
Our previous contribution attempts to evaluate Tobin’s argument that inflation “greases the
wheels” of the labor market. That is, that inflation eases the adjustment of the labor market
after an adverse shock by speeding the decline of real wages. Instead, this article examines the
recent argument that in anticipation of extreme shocks, the monetary authority should increase
inflation targets (see the literature cited above). By relaxing the usual assumption that shocks
are normally distributed and using a third-order perturbation method to solve the model, we
3In the context of financial markets, this distribution could be motivated, for example, by Stein (2014), who argues that
the most optimistic investors drive asset prices, and by Adrian and Duarte (2017), who model financial intermediaries
subject to occasionally binding value-at-risk constraints. More generally, since many economic shocks—strikes, weather,
political uncertainty, changes in commodity prices, etc.—feature long tails, the most constructive interpretation is to
think of the GEV distribution as a way to capture a wide array of potentially large disturbances that are summarized
here using a parsimonious number of structural shocks.
4As an alternative, one could consider the costs associated with the ZLB on nominal interest rates. We do not pursue
this strategy here, but refer the reader to the extensive literature on this topic (see, e.g., Coibion et al., 2012, and the
references therein).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT