EMPLOYMENT ADJUSTMENT AND LABOR UTILIZATION

AuthorIja Trapeznikova
Date01 August 2017
Published date01 August 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12239
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 3, August 2017
EMPLOYMENT ADJUSTMENT AND LABOR UTILIZATION
BYIJA TRAPEZNIKOVA1
Royal Holloway University of London, U.K
Standard models of labor adjustment assume that firms can change only the size of their workforce (the
extensive margin) and not the number of hours of their existing employees (the intensive margin) in response
to shocks. I propose a general equilibrium search model that allows for adjustment on both of these margins.
The model includes on-the-job search that generates different vacancy filling and attrition rates across firms.
I calibrate the model to a unique matched employer–employee panel of Danish firms and simulate two labor
market policies aimed at promoting job creation: hiring subsidies and a reduction in the official workweek.
1. INTRODUCTION
The variation in employment depends on the ability of firms to adjust their labor demand in
response to shocks. In the short run, firms can respond to productivity fluctuations by varying the
hours of work of their existing employees. Yet, standard economic models of labor adjustment
allow firms to change only the number of workers they employ (the extensive margin) and not
the amount that each worker works (the intensive margin). The goal of this article is to relax
this assumption and to propose and calibrate a dynamic model that includes both margins of
adjustment.
I start by documenting the importance of hours adjustment for firms’ labor demand policies.
The main reason why many of existing labor adjustment models abstract from changes in labor
utilization is the scarcity of high-frequency microdata on work hours.2This article is using a
unique matched employer–employee panel of Danish administrative firm data that contains
all private firms in the economy for the period of 1999–2006. This data set includes firm-
level information on employment and work hours on a quarterly basis. Based on these data,
I show that firms use variation in hours to economize on changes in the number of workers.
In particular, the growth rate of hours per worker and employment growth are negatively
correlated at the firm level; whereas lagged changes in hours are positively correlated with
changes in employment.3An adjustment cost model provides a natural framework for explaining
these empirical facts.
Manuscript received April 2014; revised October 2015.
1I am grateful to my late Ph.D. advisor, Dale Mortensen, for his extensive help and guidance throughout this project. I
thank the editor, Guido Menzio, and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments and suggestions. I also thank
Rasmus Lentz, Christopher Taber, Eva Nagypal, Gadi Barlevy, Eric French, Pieter Gautier, and seminar participants
at Chicago Fed, Northwestern University, Pennsylvania State University, Purdue University, Einaudi Institute for
Economics and Finance, Uppsala University, Tinbergen Institute, Aarhus University, University of Bristol, Essex
University, Oxford University, and NBER Summer Institute. This research was supported by the Labour Market
Dynamics and Growth (LMDG) project at Aarhus University. Finally, I want to express my special thanks to Henning
Bunzel for sharing his expertise on the data—this project would not exist without his invaluable help.
Please address correspondence to: Ija Trapeznikova, Department of Economics, Royal Holloway University of
London, Egham Hill, Egham, Surrey, TW20 0EX, UK. E-mail: ija.trapeznikova@rhul.ac.uk.
2The existing empirical studies are either limited to industry-level data (see, for instance, Hamermesh and Pfann,
1996) or firm-level data that are more than three decades old (for example, Cooper et al., 2007, use Longitudinal
Research Database 1972–80).
3These facts have been documented also for the U.S. labor market by Cooper et al. (2007).
889
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
890 TRAPEZNIKOVA
In this article, I develop a general equilibrium model of joint dynamics of the number of
workers and hours per worker. I extend a standard random search framework (see Mortensen
and Pissarides, 1994) to include multiworker firms with a decreasing returns to scale revenue
function. The driving force of the model is idiosyncratic profitability shocks, which firms can
accommodate by changing the work hours of their existing employees, instead of (or jointly
with) varying the size of their labor force. Hours of work and compensation in the model are
determined as an outcome of a cooperative game according to the firm’s and workers’ Shapley
values. The presence of frictions in the labor market means that matching workers with vacant
jobs takes time and uses resources. On the other hand, raising hours can be done immediately,
although at a cost of higher wages. Hence, the firm faces a trade-off between these two channels
of adjustment.
An important feature of the model is on-the-job (OTJ) search. First, job-to-job transitions
have important implications for firm-level employment dynamics: In this setup, not only does a
firm post more vacancies in the event of a positive shock, it also finds it easier to fill vacancies and
to retain its current employees, which increases the speed of employment adjustment. Second,
OTJ search is a necessary component that explains why there exists a negative correlation
between hours and employment growth rates at contracting firms. That is, firms that are hit by
a negative profitability shock face an increase in the quit rate of their existing workers. As the
number of workers keeps falling due to higher attrition, the average work hours start rising.
Finally, I find that OTJ search enables the model to capture most of the features of the data
regarding worker flows.
The model is calibrated to fit Danish firm data and is successful in capturing the overall
features of the data. Given the calibrated parameter values, I find that the average cost of
hiring a new worker is equal to about two weeks of wages. This value is low compared to the
estimates found for other European countries (see, among others, Rota, 2004; Goux et al.,
2001; and Kramarz and Michaud, 2004), reflecting the fact that the Danish labor market is very
mobile, with worker flow rates averaging around 8% per month. In the next step, I simulate
two types of policy experiments aimed at fostering job creation: (i) introducing a hiring subsidy
and (ii) imposing an upper limit on the work hours. Using this model, I can assess which of the
two policies is more effective in reducing the unemployment rate and at what cost. I find that
a hiring subsidy reduces unemployment, whereas a shorter workweek increases it, although
the effects are quantitatively small in both cases. I find considerably larger effects (or even
qualitatively different) in a “partial equilibrium” version of the model, in which the vacancy
filling rates and the quit rates are kept unchanged. These results suggest that a partial equilibrium
model significantly overestimates the effect of the adjustment costs on aggregate employment.
Moreover, I show that excluding OTJ search from the model generates counterintuitive results
in the above policy experiments, thus implying that endogenous offer acceptance and quit rates
are key not only for matching main features of the data, but also for predicting a negative effect
of hiring subsidies on unemployment.
There are two strands of literature that this work is based on. First, there is an extensive body
of research that examines the effect of adjustment costs on employment within a neoclassical
framework (see Hamermesh and Pfann, 1996, for a comprehensive survey).4Previous work that
accounts for labor utilization in adjustment cost models includes Caballero et al. (1997) and
Cooper and Willis (2009). Most of these papers are set within a partial equilibrium framework
where firms optimize their labor demand in isolation from decisions of other firms or workers.
The predictions of these models are often very different from those derived from a general
equilibrium analysis.5In contrast, my model accounts for equilibrium interactions between
4The literature on labor adjustment costs is also closely related to the investment literature (see, for example,
Caballero and Engel, 1991). Bond and Van Reenen (2007) survey econometric research on adjustment processes for
both capital and labor using microdata.
5For example, Bentolila and Bertola (1990) show that higher dismissal costs increase aggregate employment in a
partial equilibrium framework, whereas Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993) find that this prediction is actually reversed
in their general equilibrium model of heterogeneous firms with endogenous entry and exit.
EMPLOYMENT ADJUSTMENT AND LABOR UTILIZATION 891
firms and workers through a matching function and shows that hiring externalities across firms
are quantitatively very important.
Second, this article is linked to standard random search models (see, for instance, Mortensen
and Pissarides, 1994) and more recent work that introduces a theory of multiworker firms into
search models (see, for instance, Coles and Mortensen, 2016; Acemoglu and Hawkins, 2014;
and Moscarini and Postel-Vinay, 2013).6This article is most closely related to Cooper et al.
(2007), which examines the variation in hours, employment, and vacancies using U.S. data.
Given that the focus of their paper is primarily to examine the differences in labor dynamics
at the firm level and in the macrodata, they simplify labor adjustment and wage determination
processes.7Instead, I allow for richer and more realistic worker and hours dynamics across firms
by extending their model to introduce endogenous quits and joint determination of hours and
compensation.
The article proceeds as follows: Section 2 presents empirical evidence on employment and
hours adjustment using Danish firm data. Section 3 introduces and describes the model. Section
4 shows the calibration of the model and its fit to the data. Section 5 proceeds to demonstrate the
impact of policy experiments on aggregate employment and output. Section 6 summarizes the
findings. The Appendix provides details on the data sources used in this article, on the Shapley
Values, as well as on the numerical simulation procedure.
2. DATA
The Danish labor market is known for its so-called “flexicurity” (flexibility +security) model
featuring a minimum set of regulations and a generous unemployment insurance scheme. De-
spite a high level of unionization in Denmark, recent trends toward decentralization allow for
more flexibility in determining both wages and working time because many conditions can now
be negotiated at the firm level. The empirical analysis in this article is based on administrative
Danish data that contain all private firms in the economy for the period of 1999–2006 (a detailed
description of the data sources and the Danish labor market is provided in the Appendix). Em-
ployment information is drawn from a monthly matched employer–employee panel, whereas
hours data come from two sources.
The first data set is based on the Earnings survey that collects individual-level hours infor-
mation on an annual basis.8The trade-off between the number of workers and hours exists
primarily in the short run as firms eventually adjust their employment to its optimal level.
Therefore, to investigate the firm-level hours dynamics, we need to observe changes in hours
on a more frequent basis. To this end, I use the second data set drawn from firms’ mandatory
pension contributions. In Denmark, the amount of pension contributions that a firm pays for
each of its employees depends on which of the four intervals her weekly work hours fall into:
0–9, 9–18, 18–27, or more than 27 hours a week. Each firm reports the total amount of its
contributions paid for all employees over a quarter. Based on this information and the number
of workers for each firm, I compute a quarterly measure of the average hours per worker to
capture the short-term variation in the intensive margin of employment.9
6Kaas and Kircher (2015) develop a multiworker firms model within a competitive search framework that has many
similar implications for employment growth at the firm level.
7Cooper et al. (2007) simplify the wage setting mechanism by assuming that firms are paying workers their outside
option so that workers are indifferent between being employed or unemployed. In that case, job-to-job transitions
become irrelevant as workers get the same wage at all firms. Moreover, their setup implies that firms cannot adjust
wages in the case of a negative profitability shock.
8This survey covers all private firms with more than 10 full-time employees, with the exception of agriculture and
fishery.
9In particular, I use the left boundary of each nine-hour interval to obtain the lower bound (LB) measure of hours.
Alternatively, I construct an upper bound measure using the right boundary of each nine-hour interval. These two
measures behave very similarly; hence, I only report the results based on the LB measure. Appendix A.2 provides a
detailed discussion on the construction of both of these variables.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT