EFFICIENCY AND LABOR MARKET DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF LABOR SELECTION

Published date01 November 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12201
AuthorChristian Merkl,Sanjay K. Chugh
Date01 November 2016
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 4, November 2016
EFFICIENCY AND LABOR MARKET DYNAMICS IN A MODEL OF LABOR
SELECTION
BYSANJAY K. CHUGH AND CHRISTIAN MERKL1
Ohio State University, U.S.A., and Kiel Institute for the World Economy, Germany;
Friedrich-Alexander-Universit¨
at Erlangen-N¨
urnberg (FAU).Germany, Kiel Institutefor the
World Economy, Germany,and IZA Institute, Germany
This article characterizes efficient labor market allocations in a labor selection model. The model’s crucial aspect is
cross-sectional heterogeneity for new job contacts, which leads to an endogenous selection threshold for new hires. With
cross-sectional dispersion calibrated to microeconomic data, 40% of empirically relevant fluctuations in the job-finding
rate arise, which contrasts with results in an efficient search and matching economy. The efficient selection model’s
results hold in partial and general equilibrium, as well as with sequential search.
1. INTRODUCTION
This article uses microeconomic data on heterogeneity in training costs (or, more generally,
idiosyncratic productivity for new matches) to show that a labor selection model displays large
fluctuations in aggregate labor markets. Based on our microcalibration, the main result is that,
conditional on productivity shocks, roughly 40% of empirically relevant fluctuations in the
U.S. job-finding rate can be described by an efcient labor selection mechanism. These results
are several times larger than in an efficient search and matching model, and the efficient
selection model’s results hold in both partial equilibrium fluctuations and in general equilibrium
fluctuations.
Selection as an important margin of adjustment in firms’ hiring decisions is a long-standing
realistic idea, but has not been much emphasized in macro-labor analysis. An early important
empirical firm-level contribution was Barron et al. (1985, p. 50), who adopt and find strong
evidence for the view that “ . .. most employment is the outcome of an employer selecting from
a pool of job applicants ...”duetocross-sectional heterogeneity in the pool of applicants. Davis
et al. (2013) add further evidence to the view that, in their terminology, “hiring standards” play
an important role among the many margins of labor adjustment. Selection issues seemingly
would be an important component of hiring standards.
Our model’s analysis revolves around one critical microeconomic parameter, which is
the cross-sectional dispersion of new hires’ idiosyncratic training costs (or, more generally,
Manuscript received April 2013; revised July 2015.
1We thank Sushant Acharya, Susanto Basu, Matteo Cacciatore, Ryan Chahrour, Timothy Fuerst, Simon Gilchrist,
Veronica Guerrieri, Joseph Kaboski, Wolfgang Lechthaler, Guido Lorenzoni, Steven Lugauer, Michael Pries, Federico
Ravenna, Claire Reicher, Aysegul Sahin, Nicolas Vincent, and Henning Weber for useful feedback at various stages of
the project. Sanjay K. Chugh thanks the “Sch¨
oller Forschungszentrum” for financial support. Christian Merkl thanks
the Fritz Thyssen foundation for financial support during his visit at the National Bureau of Economic Research, where
the project was initiated, and the German Science Foundation (SPP 1764). Ana Lariau, Verena Maier, and Kilian
Ruppert have provided brilliant research assistance. We received helpful comments at presentations at the Federal
Reserve Board, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, the 2011 SED Meetings, the German Economic Association,
Sveriges Riksbank, the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, the Ifo Macro Seminar, the Boston College Macro Lunch
Workshop, the University of Notre Dame, the Kiel Institute, and HEC Montr´
eal.
Please address correspondence to: Christian Merkl, Friedrich-Alexander-Universit¨
at Erlangen-N¨
urnberg,
Lange Gasse 20, 90403 N ¨
urnberg, Germany. Phone: +49-911-5302-337. Fax: +49-911-5302-345. E-mail:
christian.merkl@fau.de.
1371
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
1372 CHUGH AND MERKL
idiosyncratic productivity for new workers). Taking this cross-sectional dispersion as an ex-
ogenous primitive, the model economy delivers an endogenous selection threshold for new
employees. The primary data source used to discipline this cross-sectional dispersion is the 1982
U.S. Employer Opportunity Pilot Project (EOPP), which many researchers continue to use to
this day. Our focus, unlike many others who use the rich EOPP data, is on the cross section
of new hires’ training costs; to that effect, we use the cross-sectional moments calculated by
Barron et al. (1989, table 1).
The social planner framework we construct intentionally says nothing about decentralization
via wages. However, we show in Appendix D that efficiency can be decentralized. For the sake
of robustness, we also use a second, independent, data source to discipline the cross section,
which are micro-level wage data for newly hired employees constructed by Haefke et al. (2013).
We show in two different model-based ways that the wage dispersion for newly hired employees
is a very useful information to discipline our calibration exercise. Regardless of which micro
data source is used, macro-level volatility in labor markets is an order of magnitude larger than
in an efficient search and matching framework.
We show analytically that the outside option plays a different role in efficient selection models
compared to efficient search and matching models. In the selection model, the outside option
has zero first-order effect on the steady-state elasticity of the job-finding rate with respect
to productivity. In contrast, the outside option appears directly in the search and matching
model’s steady-state elasticity of the job-finding rate with respect to productivity. In the selection
framework, the driving force for amplification is the shape of the idiosyncratic distribution at
the endogenous selection threshold.
The selection model’s results depend on a distributional assumption about heterogeneous
training characteristics (which could be interpreted as “match quality” characteristics), and, in
turn, how large the mass of individuals is that moves across the endogenously time-varying
selection threshold conditional on aggregate productivity shocks. We thus consider several
different distributions. We also allow for sequential search (`
a la McCall, 1970; Mortensen,
1970) to permit an arbitrary number of “job arrivals” or “interviews” (and hence an arbitrary
number of “match-quality” realizations) during a given time period. The quantitative results,
of course, differ slightly as we vary distributions and vary the number of per-period contacts
(also known as the job arrival rate) via sequential search within an empirically plausible range,
but the main result remains the same: An efficient labor selection model provides powerful
amplification effects on job-finding rates and unemployment rates in response to productivity
shocks.
Focusing the model on selection effects and efficiency allows us to highlight that no other
frictions are needed to deliver sharp fluctuations in the labor market, which makes the intuition
easy to understand.2,3This focus on selection does not deny that other frictions, be they on
quantities or on prices, do not or cannot play an important role in macro-labor dynamics.
Rather, our focus on efficient selection is meant as a first step.
Extensively studied in the literature is the role of search and matching frictions, along with
frameworks such as the involuntary unemployment framework of Christiano et al. (2010), the
rigid-wage class of models as in Gali (2011) and Gali et al. (2012), as well as earlier versions
of the labor selection model incorporating New Keynesian pricing frictions and wage-setting
frictions, such as Lechthaler et al. (2010). These various models, based on different primitives
and distortions, do not disentangle the amplification effects that are due to efficient surplus
splitting versus inefficient surplus splitting. The point of our work is to analytically and quan-
titatively analyze efficient allocations in a tractable dynamic selection model, in a way that
2Carlsson et al. (2013) find that the market tightness of local labor markets in Sweden does not affect job creation.
This suggests that other margins such as labor selection may be at work.
3Although this focus on one margin of the labor market (namely, selection) may seem extreme at first sight, it is
similar to many search and matching papers that assume that all workers who make a contact with a firm get matched.
This is the case if the matching function is interpreted as a contact function (i.e., contact is endogenous, whereas
selection is exogenous). For a further discussion of this issue, see Brown et al. (2015).
EFFICIENT LABOR SELECTION DYNAMICS 1373
can be traced all the way back to the early indivisible (and efficient) labor models of Hansen
(1985) and Rogerson (1988). Our model and its workings has interpretations in terms of the
indivisible labor models of Hansen (1985) and Rogerson (1988), and it has connections with
their generalization in terms of heterogeneity developed in Mulligan (2001).
The rest of the article is organized as follows: Section 2 describes the details of the selection
model, derives analytical results for the efficient partial equilibrium version, and provides
some intuition. Section 3 shows quantitative results in partial equilibrium and checks for the
robustness of these results. Section 4 enlarges the model to general equilibrium by including
endogenous labor force participation (LFP) and an aggregate goods resource constraint, in
which the labor market results carry through. Section 5 concludes.
2. LABOR MARKETS I:ANALYTICS
This section defines the basic labor market setup and notation that will be used throughout
the article. To focus on the main results of the model, both Sections 2 and 3 abstract from
consumption markets and hence could be thought of “partial equilibrium.”
2.1. Structure of Labor Market. There are two central features of the model. First, each
newly selected worker imposes training costs on his employer (or, more generally, he draws a
match-specific idiosyncratic shock).4The training costs consist of a fixed component, γh>0,
and an idiosyncratic component, εi
t, for newly hired individual i. The idiosyncratic component is
revealed only when a potential worker makes contact with a firm, as shown in Figure 1, below.
The idiosyncratic component of training is the “match quality” cost in our analysis.5There is a
continuum of production units, each of which is constant-returns-to-scale and homogenous in
all other respects.
This is the second central feature of the model: Depending on his training costs realized at
a specific production unit, the potential new worker may or may not be hired. If not hired,
the individual makes finitely many more “meetings with” or “contacts with” (we use the terms
“meeting,” “contact,” “job arrival,” and“job offer” synonymously) another firm, at which he
may have had a lower contact-specific training cost, during the same period. This latter aspect of
the model is the well-known sequential search model. Until we incorporate sequential search in
Section 3, suppose that each individual available to be selected for work in a given time period
makes contact with one arbitrary production unit with probability 1. The one-contact-per-period
framework conveys virtually all of the economic intuition of the article.
From a planning perspective, it is thus efficient to hire only those individuals with sufficiently
attractive characteristics. Sufficiency is characterized by an endogenous state-contingent selec-
tion threshold, ˜εt. Because individual i’s idiosyncratic characteristics are defined as a cost,heis
hired only if εi
t˜εt. Training costs are i.i.d. across worker–firm pairs within any given period and
across time periods, with probability density function f(εt). Selection occurs with endogenous
probability ηεt), which is the cumulative distribution function of ε; all searching individuals
being considered for a job draw from the same distribution.
Both the fixed component of training costs γhand the idiosyncratic component of training
costs εi
tare measured in units of output, and they are incurred in only the rst period of a
new employment relationship.6In contrast, each incumbent worker has zero training costs and
produces stochastic output ztin period t. Newly hired worker iproduces output net of training
costs ztεi
tγh.
4We will interchangeably refer to “firms” and “production units” in what follows because of the linearity of the
production technology and the fact that we study only efficient allocations, so the manner in which employment
surpluses are split via wages in a decentralized economy does not affect the results.
5There is no traditional matching function in the model as in the Pissarides (1985) framework. One could suppose
that a simple matching, or “contact,” function exists in which the measure of contacts equals the number of searching
individuals.
6Individuals who have been employed for more than one period are identical in their characteristics.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT