CEO power and corporate risk: The impact of market competition and corporate governance

Date01 September 2019
Published date01 September 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/corg.12285
AuthorShahbaz Sheikh
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
CEO power and corporate risk: The impact of market
competition and corporate governance
Shahbaz Sheikh
DAN Department of Management and
Organizational Studies, The University of
Western Ontario, London, Ontario, Canada
Correspondence
Shahbaz Sheikh, DAN Department of
Management and Organizational Studies, The
University of Western Ontario, London,
Ontario, Canada.
Email: ssheik2@uwo.ca
Abstract
Research Question/Issue: Although there is no unified theory that can explain the
relationship between CEO power and corporate risk, the empirical evidence generally
finds a positive association. This study argues that market competition and corporate
governance play critical roles in influencing this relationship.
Research Findings/Insights: Using a large panel of nonfinancial U.S. corporations
for the period 19922015, I find that CEO power is positively associated with total
and idiosyncratic measures of risk. However, this positive association remains signif-
icant only when market competition is high or corporate governance is strong.
Theoretical/Academic Implications: The research design of this study combines
the predictions of agency theory, the behavioral agency model, and prospect theory
to further our understanding of the relationship between CEO power and corporate
risk, including consideration of how competition and corporate governance influence
this relationship.
Practitioner/Policy Implications: The empirical evidence presented in this study
can help boards to more accurately gauge when CEO power is most beneficial in
terms of optimal levels of corporate risk and to better understand the relationship
between power and risk. The results suggest that boards should grant more power
to their CEOs when their firms operate in highcompetition markets or have strong
corporate governance in place.
KEYWORDS
corporate governance, CEO power, idiosyncratic risk, market competition, total risk
1|INTRODUCTION
The position of CEO is regarded as a source of power (Hamori &
Kakarika, 2009), and CEOs are often perceived as chief planners and
architects of a firm's longterm strategy (Berger, Dutta, Raffel, & Sam-
uels, 2008). CEOs make key investment and financing decisions that
affect corporate risk and value. CEO ability to influence these decisions
and thus the level of corporate risk depends on how much power they
enjoy relative to their boards and other team members. Although no
unified theory can explain exactly how CEO power affects corporate
risk, there are a few competing views on this relationship. Agency
theory (Jensen & Meckling, 1976), for example, argues that CEOs are
risk averse and poorly diversified, tending to take less risk than the
diversified shareholders would like them to (Amihud & Lev, 1981;
Eisenhardt, 1989; Holmstrom, 1999; Smith & Stulz, 1985). Agency the-
ory further holds that CEOs have incentives to divert corporate
resources to their private benefit by forgoing valueincreasing risky pro-
jects. Because the ability to both divert corporate resources and make
conservative investment decisions increases with power, agency theory
predicts that powerful CEOs tend to reduce corporate risk.
Agency theory focuses only on cases of CEOs who are either risk
averse or risk neutral and ignores cases where they are risk seekers
Received: 2 March 2018 Revised: 26 April 2019 Accepted: 29 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/corg.12285
358 © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd Corp Govern Int Rev. 2019;27:358377.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/corg
(e.g., Carpenter, Pollock, & Leary, 2003; Sanders & Hambrick, 2007;
Wiseman & GomezMejia, 1998). Prospect theory (Kahneman &
Tversky, 1979), however, argues that individuals exhibit variable risk
preferences and may avoid or seek risk, depending on a reference
point.
1
It suggests that depending on expected prospects, CEOs may
actually increase risk. Similarly, studies in social psychology (e.g.,
Anderson & Galinsky, 2006) stipulate that powerful CEOs are more
optimistic about the intrinsic payoffs of their decisions and tend to
disregard potential dangers inherent in their decisions. Powerful CEOs
are often overconfident about their skills, with a greater potential for
costly judgment errors while making risky investment decisions
(Adams, Almeida, & Ferreira, 2005; Sah & Stiglitz, 1986, 1991). Conse-
quently, the likelihood of extreme outcomes (either very good or very
bad) and the variability of firm performance (risk) are high when CEOs
have more power (Adams et al., 2005; Hirshleifer, Low, & Teoh, 2012).
Prospect and social psychology theories suggest that powerful CEOs
tend to increase corporate risk.
The empirical evidence on the relationship between CEO power
and corporate risk is also mixed, though a number of studies report a
positive association (e.g., Adams et al., 2005; Lewellyn & MullerKahle,
2012). In this study, I argue that market competition and corporate
governance play critical roles in influencing the relationship between
CEO power and corporate risk. Failure to control for these mechanisms
may have led to the conflicting results in prior literature. Understand-
ing the effects of competition and corporate governance is important
because they impose external discipline and improve quality of moni-
toring, especially when CEOs wield substantial power (Fama, 1980;
Giroud & Mueller, 2010, 2011; Shleifer & Vishney, 1989).
Market competition imposes external discipline by increasing the
probability of failure and by making a firm a more attractive takeover
target (Paligorova & Yang, 2014). Higher competition also increases
the risk of bankruptcy and the likelihood of performancerelated
CEO turnover (Dasgupta, Li, & Wang, 2017). Higher competition thus
motivates managers to make risky but valueincreasing investments to
keep the company competitive and save their jobs (Grossman & Hart,
1983; Hart, 1983; Schmidt, 1997). Higher competition simultaneously
decreases opportunities for quiet lifeby inducing effortaverse man-
agers to make risky investment decisions.
2
Because powerful CEOs
are often overconfidentand people tend to be more confident about
their performance on difficult rather than easy tasks (Griffin &
Tversky, 1992)they may make more risky decisions when competi-
tion is high and decision making becomes more challenging.
Strong corporate governance (investor protection) improves quality
of monitoring and restricts managerial ability to expropriate corporate
resources. Strong governance induces powerful CEOs not to forgo
valueincreasing risky investment projects in order to divert corporate
resources to their personal benefit (John, Litov, & Yeung, 2008). Strong
corporate governance also motivates CEOs to give up quiet life and
make difficult and risky investment decisions. Both high market com-
petition and strong corporate governance therefore motivate CEOs
to exercise their power and increase corporate risk.
In order to test how market competition and corporate governance
affect the relationship between CEO power and corporate risk, I
collect data on a large panel of U.S. firms for the period 19922015.
Drawing on Finkelstein (1992), I construct a multidimensional index
of CEO power that incorporates six different sources of power. I use
the HerfindahlHirschman index (HHI) to measure market competition
and the governance index (Gindex) of Gompers, Ishii, and Metrick
(2003) to measure corporate governance.
3
Results indicate that CEO power is positively associated with two
measures of corporate risk: total risk and idiosyncratic risk. Further
tests show that this relationship is influenced by market competition
and corporate governance. Specifically, CEO power is positively asso-
ciated with corporate risk only when firms operate in highcompetition
markets or have strong corporate governance in place. When market
competition is low or corporate governance is weak, CEO power does
not have a significant impact on corporate risk.
The empirical results in this study are robust to alternative mea-
sures of market competition, corporate governance, and firm risk.
These results remain similar when CEO power is treated as endoge-
nous and the relationship is estimated using instrumental variable
regressions. Finally, results do not change when a 2year lag is used
between corporate risk, CEO power, and other control variables; when
CEO power is measured with a categorical variable instead of the
power index; or when the sample is divided into subsamples based
on high market competition and strong corporate governance.
This study contributes to the literature on CEO power and corpo-
rate risk in two distinct ways. First, it shows that powerful CEOs tend
to increase corporate risk only when market competition is high or
corporate governance is strong. Previous studies have separately
examined the relationship between CEO power and corporate risk
(e.g., Chintrakarn, Jiraporn, & Tong, 2015; Pathan, 2009), market com-
petition and corporate risk (Laksmana & Yang, 2015), and corporate
governance and corporate risk (e.g., John et al., 2008). There is no
study to my knowledge that explores the effect of market competition
and corporate governance on the relationship between CEO power
and corporate risk.
Second, it provides further support for the existing stream of
research that demonstrates a positive relationship between CEO
power and corporate risk. It finds a robust positive effect of CEO
power on corporate risk using a measure of CEO power that is differ-
ent from previous studies using a larger panel of firms. In this respect,
it complements the empirical findings of Adams et al. (2005) and
Lewellyn and MullerKahle (2012).
2|THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND
RELATED LITERATURE
This study attempts to explain the effects of market competition and
corporate governance on the relationship between CEO power and
corporate risk and not corporate risk taking. Although corporate risk
taking influences corporate risk, they are considered to be distinct
(Palmer & Wiseman, 1999) in the strategic management literature.
Corporate risk is measured by total risk and idiosyncratic risk, which
are calculated from daily stock returns. Corporate risk taking is
SHEIKH 359

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT