CAPITAL‐ AND LABOR‐SAVING TECHNICAL CHANGE IN AN AGING ECONOMY

Published date01 February 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12216
Date01 February 2017
AuthorAndreas Irmen
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 58, No. 1, February 2017
CAPITAL- AND LABOR-SAVING TECHNICAL CHANGE IN AN AGING
ECONOMY
BYANDREAS IRMEN1
CREA, University of Luxembourg, and CESifo, Munich, Germany
Does population aging and the associated increase in the old-age dependency ratio affect economic growth? The
answer is given in a novel analytical framework that allows for population aging to affect endogenous capital- and
labor-saving technical change. In a steady state capital-saving technical progress vanishes, and the economy’s growth
rate of per-capita variables reflects only labor-saving technical change. The mere possibility of capital-saving technical
change is shown to imply that the economy’s steady-state growth rate becomes independent of its age structure: Neither
a higher life expectancy nor a decline in fertility affects economic growth in the long run.
1. INTRODUCTION
Population aging, defined as the process by which older individuals become a proportionally
larger fraction of the total population, has been the predominant demographic phenomenon
in many countries over the last decades and is forecast to reach unprecedented heights. As
a concomitant phenomenon the United Nations predicts a substantial increase in the old-age
dependency ratio (OADR) of many countries and regions. Whereas the current level of this
ratio is around 0.2 in the United States and 0.24 in Europe, the respective predictions for 2050
are 0.36 and 0.47.2
There is widespread consensus that these trends have two main causes, a decline in fertility
and an increase in longevity (see, e.g., Weil, 2008).3This article starts from this premise and asks
whether and how population aging and the associated increase in the OADR affect economic
growth. In particular, I argue that firms adjust their innovation investments in aging economies.
Since these investments constitute a crucial determinant of the speed of technical progress,
population aging has the potential to affect the growth performance of an economy both in the
short run and in the long run.
I address this issue in a novel growth model that allows for endogenous capital- and labor-
saving technical change. This feature turns out to substantially modify the predicted effects
Manuscript received February 2015; revised October 2015.
1This article is a revised version of my CREA Discussion Paper (Irmen, 2013a). Financial support from the University
of Luxembourg under the program “Agecon C—Population Aging: An Exploration of Its Effect on Economic Perfor-
mance and Culture” is gratefully acknowledged. I would like to thank two anonymous referees and an associate editor
for helpful comments. I thank D´
eborah Schwartz and Amer Tabakovic for competent research assistance. This article
also benefited from useful suggestions provided by Volker B¨
ohm, Raouf Boucekkine, Oded Galor, Hendrik Hakenes,
Burkhard Heer, Johanna Kuehnel, Anastasia Litina, Isabel Schnabel, Robert Stelter, Gautam Tripati, Edgar Vogel,
Benteng Zou, and seminar audiences at several academic institutions. Please address correspondence to: Andreas
Irmen, CREA, Faculty of Law, Economics and Finance, University of Luxembourg, 162a, avenue de la Fa¨
ıencerie,
L-1511 Luxembourg, Luxembourg. E-mail: airmen@uni.lu.
2Here, the OADR is expressed as the ratio of the population aged 65 or over to the population aged 15–64. The
predicted numbers correspond to the “medium fertility variant” presented in United Nations (2013). For countries like
China, India, Japan, and for the entire planet, the predicted increase of the OADR over the same period is even more
pronounced. I focus on the OADR as an indicator of population aging since this measure has a natural counterpart in
the theoretical analysis that follows.
3During a demographic transition, a decline in fertility will increase the OADR because fewer young people enter
the labor force than there are old workers leaving it. A higher longevity means an increase in the number of years an
individual is old. This increases the OADR by raising the number of retired persons alive.
261
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
262 IRMEN
of population aging on economic growth. The production side of the economy builds on and
extends ideas of the so-called “induced innovations” literature (see, e.g., Hicks, 1932; Drandakis
and Phelps, 1966). According to this literature, relative factor prices reflect the relative scarcity
of factors and induce innovations that raise the productivity of the relatively scarcer and more
expensive factor. In line with this reasoning, my framework highlights that population aging
increases the relative scarcity of labor with respect to capital. This tendency increases the real
wage relative to the real rental rate of capital and induces more labor-saving and less capital-
saving technical change.4However, unlike the “induced innovations” literature, the investment
behavior of competitive firms is fully microfounded in this article. To accomplish this, I introduce
a production function defined over “types of tasks” performed by either capital or labor.
The household side has two-period lived overlapping generations (OLGs) as in Allais (1947),
Samuelson (1958), or Diamond (1965). Individuals face a survival probability when they enter
the second period of their lives. This framework allows for a straightforward representation of
population aging as an increase in the OADR. Both a decline in fertility and an increase in the
survival probability of the current young augment this ratio in the next period.
The main result of my analysis concerns the relationship between population aging and
economic growth in the long run. I establish that the steady-state growth rate of per-capita
variables is given by the growth rate of labor-saving technological knowledge alone. Moreover,
this growth rate is independent of population aging. The latter property is shown to be due to
the mere possibility of endogenous capital-saving technical change.
The intuition behind this finding is linked to the logic of the generalized steady-state growth
theorem devised in Irmen (2013b). This theorem generalizes Uzawa’s steady-state growth
theorem (Uzawa, 1961) to endogenous-growth economies including the one studied in this
article. Roughly speaking, it states that only labor-saving technical change can occur in the
steady state of a neoclassical economy that uses some of its current output to generate technical
progress. Thus, asymptotically, capital-saving technical change must vanish. For the steady state
of the economy under scrutiny, here this requires that the stock of capital-saving technological
knowledge remains constant over time. Hence, the steady state must induce capital-saving
technical progress just sufficient to offset the depreciation of this stock. This requirement
determines a time-invariant steady-state level of the “efficient capital intensity,” the economy’s
state variable. The determination of this level reflects two facets of the production sector,
namely, the way capital-saving technological knowledge accumulates and the conditions for
profit maximization of firms that undertake capital-saving innovation investments. Population
aging does not interfere with its determination. As the steady-state level of the efficient capital
intensity also determines the growth rate of labor-saving technical progress, the steady-state
growth rate of the economy does not hinge on population aging either.
There are at least two ways to link this finding to the recent experience of the U.S. economy.
First, the evolution of the OADR and of per-capita GDP growth over the period 1960–2012
appear uncorrelated in the data.5Whereas the OADR trends upward, the evolution of the
growth rate of per-capita GDP is driven by short-run fluctuations around a constant trend.
These features are consistent with the near steady-state behavior of the economy under scrutiny
here. Since the steady-state growth rate is independent of the OADR, there is a neighborhood
of the locally stable steady state where fluctuations of per-capita GDP growth remain small
even if the OADR increases. Second, as shown by Klump et al. (2007) for the period 1953–1998,
4This chain of reasoning associates the phenomenon of population aging with the famous contention of John Hicks
(1932, pp. 124–125) on induced inventions according to which “a change in the relative prices of the factors of production
is itself a spur to invention, and to invention of a particular kind—directed to economizing the use of a factor that
has become relatively expensive. The general tendency to a more rapid increase of capital than labor that has marked
European history during the last few centuries has naturally provided a stimulus to labor-saving inventions.”
5To confirm this statement, I regressed U.S. per-capita GDP on the OADR and a time trend using data from the
World Bank (2013) for the above-mentioned period. The coefficient on OADR is statistically insignificant with a p-
value greater than 0.6. The same qualitative finding obtains if, in the regression, per-capita GDP growth is replaced by
labor productivity growth. The detailed regression results are available from the author upon request.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT