APPROPRIATE TECHNOLOGY AND INCOME DIFFERENCES

Date01 August 2016
Published date01 August 2016
AuthorDozie Okoye
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12182
INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW
Vol. 57, No. 3, August 2016
APPROPRIATE TECHNOLOGY AND INCOME DIFFERENCES
BYDOZIE OKOYE1
Dalhousie University, Canada
This article studies the relative productivity of skilled to unskilled workers across countries. Relative productivities
are broken down into the human capital embodied in skilled workers and relative physical productivities (reflecting
production techniques). I find that skilled workers from poorer countries embody less human capital and are also
relatively less physically productive. Furthermore, results show that production techniques are inappropriate for most
low-income countries, and these countries experience large increases in GDP per capita by increasing the relative
physical productivity of skilled to unskilled workers. This suggests that there are significant barriers to the adoption of
skill-complementary technologies.
1. INTRODUCTION
An important problem in development economics, and economic growth, is understanding
how economies use available factors of production. The conventional view is that low-income
countries use available factors unproductively compared to richer countries. Recent studies have
found significant productivity differences between sectors in low-income countries, and there
is an emerging view that low-income countries are not unproductive at everything. Examples
include productivity differences between agricultural and nonagricultural sectors (Restuccia
et al., 2008; Gollin et al., 2011), differences in productivity by sectoral skill intensity (Acemoglu
and Zilibotti, 2001; Ciccone and Papaioannou, 2009), and sectoral differences in productivity
based on tradability of the final good (Herrendorf and Valentinyi, 2012).
Looking across factors of production, Caselli and Coleman (2006) find that in comparison
to high-income countries, low-income countries use unskilled workers relatively more produc-
tively than the skilled. In fact, they find that that low-income countries use unskilled workers
absolutely more productively than richer countries under their preferred set of parameters.
However, the methodology in Caselli and Coleman (2006) cannot distinguish the hypothesis
that skilled workers in low-income countries are less productive because they have less em-
bodied human capital from the hypothesis that skilled workers are less productive because
low-income countries adopt technologies that are (more) complementary with unskilled work-
ers.2For example, are doctors in the United States more productive than doctors in Liberia
because they are generally better trained (higher embodied human capital), or because they
Manuscript received June 2014; revised April 2015.
1I am grateful to Elizabeth Caucutt, Igor Livshits, James B. Davies, the editor, and two anonymous referees for
insightful comments and suggestions that greatly improved the article. I also wish to thank participants at the UWO
Macro Lunch and Dalhousie University’s Macro and Economic Development group for remarks on earlier drafts.
Comments from participants at the 2013 Canadian Economics Association meetings are also acknowledged. All errors
are mine.
Please address correspondence to: Dozie Okoye, Department of Economics, Dalhousie University, 6214 University
Ave., Halifax, NS, B3H 4R2, Canada. Phone: +902-494-4453. E-mail: cokoye@dal.ca.
2They fully acknowledge this possibility and use information on the elasticity of human capital to measures of
schooling inputs to argue that human capital quality differences are small and can only explain a small fraction of the
differences in physical productivities. However, recent studies, using different data to back out human capital quality,
have found considerable cross-country differences in the quality of skilled labor. In many cases, differences in the
quality of skilled labor are as large as differences in the quantity of skilled labor (Manuelli and Seshadri, 2005; Erosa
et al., 2010; Schoellman, 2012).
955
C
(2016) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
956 OKOYE
have access to better equipment such as MRI machines (higher physical productivities), or
both?3
To answer the question mentioned above, I first extend the methodology in Caselli and
Coleman (2006) and explain how cross-country differences in the productivity of skilled workers
(relative to the unskilled) can be decomposed into differences in the amount of human capital
embodied in skilled workers and differences in production techniques, or what I call physical
productivities. This is done using estimates of skill premiums for immigrants from different
countries living in the United States and estimates of skill premiums across countries. The
intuition is that since all skilled workers in the United States work with the same technologies,
any differences in skill premiums by country of origin within the United States must be due to
differences in embodied human capital.4Further, controlling for cross-country differences in
the supply of skilled workers, any differences in skill premiums for immigrants in the United
States and those left behind in their home countries must be due to differences in physical
productivities (production techniques).
I find that (compared to richer countries) skilled workers in low-income countries have
significantly less embodied human capital. The physical productivity of skilled workers is also
higher in high-income countries, implying that they are used more productively relative to
unskilled workers. This result holds for various plausible parameterization of the production
function. Compared to the productivity of skilled workers relative to the unskilled in Caselli
and Coleman (2006), controlling for embodied human capital means that differences in the
physical productivity of skilled workers are smaller. However, large differences in physical
productivities still remain because differences in embodied human capital are small, compared
to differences in physical productivities. For example, the ratio of embodied human capital in
Ghanaian skilled workers relative to their American counterparts is about 3.6, which is small
compared to the 50-fold difference in the physical productivity of skilled relative to unskilled
workers.
I then investigate the appropriateness of physical productivities. For example, are skilled
workers relatively unproductive in Ghana because Ghanaian firms appropriately choose tech-
nologies which make abundant unskilled workers more productive? I argue that the estimates
imply that this is unlikely: In Ghana, the estimates imply that skilled workers are 50 times less
physically productive compared to unskilled workers, and in Venezuela they are 100 times less
productive. However, the data show that there are just as many skilled and unskilled workers
in Ghana and Venezuela. It is unlikely that unskilled workers being 50 times as physically
productive as skilled workers is appropriate, given that skilled workers are just as numerous,
possess more human capital, and are substitutable with unskilled workers.
To formally investigate, I compare the estimated relative physical productivity of skilled
workers to what they would be if technologies were chosen by profit-maximizing firms in each
country, following models of appropriate technology.5For most of the 49 countries in the data
set, the estimated physical productivities of skilled workers are significantly lower than what
is optimal. This is true under various definitions of skilled–unskilled labor and values of the
skilled–unskilled labor elasticity of substitution. Furthermore, the distance between estimated
and optimal physical productivity of skilled workers is decreasing with GDP-per-capita. For
3This is an important distinction because the source of the higher productivity of skilled workers has different policy
implications. If doctors in high-income countries are primarily more productive because they are better trained, this
would imply important differences in the quality of doctors across countries. On the other hand, if doctors are more
productive in high-income countries because of access to better medical equipment, it would imply significant barriers
to technology adoption.
4Although immigrants are positively selected on schooling, Schoellman (2012) provides evidence that the return to
schooling for immigrants is robust to selection problems. Similar patterns are found when the sample is restricted to
refugees and asylum seekers who are a less-selected group of immigrants.
5The shape of the technology frontier available to firms is assumed to be the same across countries, but the height of
the frontier or number of available technologies is allowed to vary by country. This is in contrast to Caselli and Coleman
(2006), who estimate the technology frontier assuming that firms in every country choose technologies appropriately,
but also allow the shape and the height to vary across countries.
TECHNOLOGY AND INCOME DIFFERENCES 957
richer countries such as South Korea, Japan, Israel, the Netherlands, and Australia, we cannot
reject that they use skilled and unskilled workers appropriately. For other countries, such as
Thailand, India, Venezuela, Ghana, and Kenya, the estimated physical productivity of skilled
workers is four times less than what is appropriate.
It is important to see that the finding that the estimated mix of skilled–unskilled physi-
cal productivities is inappropriate is independent of the exact shape of the world technology
frontier. This is because many countries could increase output by using the estimated mix of
skilled–unskilled physical productivity of other countries in the data. For example, Ghana could
increase GDP per capita by a factor of 2.5 simply by using the mix of skilled–unskilled physical
productivities used by Ecuador or Greece, leaving all else the same. This implies that with-
out knowing the country-specific technology frontier, there is a possible mix of technologies
that would increase income in many low-income countries by making skilled workers more
productive relative to the unskilled.
This finding also differs from regular notions of appropriate technology, which argue that poor
countries use technologies that are appropriate for a high-skilled workforce, but inappropriate
for their relatively unskilled workforce. The result here is in fact the opposite; controlling for
the human capital embodied in skilled workers, low-income countries tend to use technologies
that make skilled workers very unproductive and unskilled workers too productive. This sug-
gests significant income gains by adopting more technologies that make skilled workers more
productive and unskilled workers less productive.
To get a sense of potential income gains from using more appropriate and skill-complementary
technologies, I compare income per capita with estimated physical productivities to income per
capita under the optimal physical productivity of skilled workers. Note that in this exercise,
all factors of production are held constant, and only the relative productivity of skilled and
unskilled workers is changing. Under the preferred set of parameters, the average country in
the data increases its income per capita by a factor of 2 from using its appropriate technology
and increasing the relative physical productivity of skilled workers.
There is some variation in income gains from adopting appropriate technologies, depending
on a country’s income relative to the United States. Countries in the lowest income quartile
experience a sevenfold increase in income, because they are farthest away from their optimal
mix of skilled–unskilled physical productivities. More than 50% of all countries in the data set
could increase incomes by a factor of 4 from adopting the appropriate mix of skilled–unskilled
worker complementary technologies. Countries in the top income quartile only experience a
23% increase in income by adopting their appropriate technologies, and most of the gains are
driven by France and Greece.
These results could be interpreted as the result of significant barriers to technology adoption,
in a world in which new technologies are complementary with skilled workers.6As tradi-
tional technologies are complementary with unskilled workers, the adoption of newer skilled-
complementary technologies are readily blocked by vested interests, rendering skilled workers
relatively less productive than they could be.7A report by McKinsey (2001) documents the
prevalent nonadoption of more productive technologies in many Indian sectors. A recent ex-
ample is the resistance to Walmart’s entry into the Indian retail market by small-scale retailers
(see the Bloomberg news report by Pradhan and MacAskill, 2011).
The inefficient use of skilled workers could also be a result of financial frictions, which may
prevent firms from adopting modern technologies (Greenwood and Jovanovic, 1990; Buera
and Shin, 2010; Greenwood et al., 2010). In particular, Midrigan and Xu (2014) find that the
effect of financial frictions on productivity is primarily due to its distortionary effects on the
decision to enter the modern sector and adopt modern technologies. Furthermore, the lack
6See Acemoglu (2002), Berman et al. (1998), and Ciccone and Papaioannou (2009) for evidence that recent tech-
nologies have been skilled biased.
7For examples of how vested interests can block the adoption of new technologies, see Bridgman et al. (2007) and
Bellettini and Ottaviano (2005).

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT