AN ANATOMY OF U.S. PERSONAL BANKRUPTCY UNDER CHAPTER 13

AuthorWenli Li,Hülya Eraslan,Gizem Koşar,Pierre‐Daniel Sarte
Published date01 August 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/iere.12231
Date01 August 2017
INTERNATIONAL
ECONOMIC
REVIEW
August 2017
Vol. 58, No. 3
AN ANATOMY OF U.S. PERSONAL BANKRUPTCY UNDER CHAPTER 13
BYH¨
ULYA ERASLAN,GIZEM KOS¸AR,WENLI LI,AND PIERRE-DANIEL SARTE1
Rice University, U.S.A.; Federal Reserve Bank of New York,U.S.A.; Federal Reserve Bank of
Philadelphia, U.S.A.; Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, U.S.A.
We build a structural model that captures salient features of personal bankruptcy under Chapter 13. We
estimate our model using a novel data set that we construct from bankruptcies filed in Delaware between 2001
and 2002. Our estimation results highlight the importance of a debtor’s choice of repayment plan length on
other Chapter 13 outcomes. We use the estimated model to conduct policy experiments to evaluate the impact
of more stringent laws that impose restrictions on the length of repayment plans. We find that these provisions
would not materially affect creditor recovery rates and would not necessarily make discharge more likely.
In short, the bankruptcy system operates behind a veil of darkness created by the lack of reliable data
about its operations.The lack of information about “what is going on” in the bankruptcy system leads to
a distrust of its results—a belief by some that creditors, debtors,and professionals within the system are
all somehow taking advantage of one another and the public at large, and that the system suffers from
widespread fraud, abuse, and inefciency.
1997 National Bankruptcy Commission
1. INTRODUCTION
On April 20, 2005, the Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act
(BAPCPA) was signed into law and ended a comprehensive legislative effort that began
under the Clinton administration. The new personal bankruptcy law imposed many new (and
controversial) changes, including higher filing fees, “means test” on debtors contemplating a
bankruptcy filing, and longer length payment plans. The aim was to ensure that debtors with
sufficient income would file under Chapter 13. The key presumption underlying this provision
was that a large number of households did not repay as much as their income allowed. In
Manuscript received January 2011; revised May 2016.
1We are grateful to Philip Bond, Bob Hunt, Steven Stern, Ken Wolpin, Holger Sieg, and two anonymous referees for
helpful comments and suggestions. We also thank seminar participants at the University of Pennsylvania, the Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, FDIC, 2007 Society of Economic Dynamics Summer Meetings, the Florida International
University, Southern Methodist University, University of Oxford, and University of Virginia. Ishani Tewari and Sarah
Carroll provided excellent research assistance. We acknowledge financial support from the FDIC Center for Financial
Research, Wharton Financial Institutions Center, and Rodney White Center for Financial Research. Finally, we are
indebted to Michael Joseph, the Chapter 13 Trustee for the District of Delaware, for numerous conversations and
e-mail exchanges that have enhanced our understanding of bankruptcy law and its practice. The views expressed here
are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia, the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, or the Federal Reserve System.
Please address correspondence to: Wenli Li, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, 10 N. Independence Mall W.,
Philadelphia, PA 19106. E-mail: Wenli.Li@phil.frb.org.
671
C
(2017) by the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and the Osaka University Institute of Social
and Economic Research Association
672 ERASLANETAL.
particular, it was thought that Chapter 13 would perform better both as a collection device for
creditors and as a means to provide debtors with a financial fresh start, if stricter rules were
imposed on repayment plans.
The objective of our article is to take a first step at evaluating the impact of these stricter
rules. Specifically, we aim to assess the effect of section 1325, paragraph 4, which was added to
the U.S. Bankruptcy Code under BAPCPA and imposes additional restrictions on the length
of repayment plans for debtors with income above the state median. To do so, we build and
estimate a structural model of Chapter 13 bankruptcy using a novel data set we construct. For
a side contribution, we provide empirical evidence regarding the outcomes under Chapter 13
and its performance both as a collection device for creditors and as a means to provide debtors
with a financial fresh start.
Our model captures the salient features of personal bankruptcy under Chapter 13. In our
model, a debtor first makes decisions regarding whether or not to file under Chapter 13 and, if so,
what repayment plan to propose. Since the law requires that all of a debtor’s excess income be
applied to his repayment plan, the debtor’s choice of repayment plan boils down to its length.2In
choosing what plan to propose, the debtor recognizes that its duration has a bearing on the confir-
mation outcome that is determined by the recommendations of a bankruptcy trustee appointed
to oversee the bankruptcy process. Under the bankruptcy law, in deciding whether to confirm
a plan or not, the trustee must form an opinion as to the fairness and feasibility of the plan. The
fairness condition is satisfied as long as the debtor contributes all excess income into the plan pay-
ments. The feasibility condition requires that the debtor’s excess income is sufficient to pay the
unsecured creditors over a three- to five-year period an amount no less than they can recover un-
der liquidation of the debtor’s assets. To capture the idea that the trustee has some leeway in the
interpretation of the bankruptcy law, in our model, whether the trustee views a given plan as fair
and feasible or not is random from the perspective of the debtor. Specifically, whether the trustee
views a plan as fair and feasible depends on the debtor’s characteristics and the plan length.
Even if a plan is initially confirmed, it may nonetheless become unfair or infeasible due
to fluctuations in the debtor’s financial condition. We model this possibility by introducing
shocks to income or expenses of the debtor at a random date. Following the shocks, the trustee
reevaluates the feasibility of the plan under the new debtor characteristics. If the case is not
dismissed, the debtor decides whether to continue or voluntarily default on his plan.
Overall, our model highlights a basic trade-off debtors face in proposing long repayment
plans versus short ones. Long repayment plans are costly in that they impose restraints on
debtors for longer periods, but these plans may also be more likely to be confirmed by the
court and, ultimately, to result in a financial fresh start. In addition, our model highlights the
importance of shocks to excess income during the bankruptcy process. In particular, even
though a plan may be fair and feasible at the time a debtor files for Chapter 13 bankruptcy, it
may cease to be so later on before the repayment plan is complete.
We estimate our model using newly collected data contained in court files on all Chapter
13 personal bankruptcies recorded by the U.S. Bankruptcy Court for the District of Delaware
between August 2001 and August 2002. From the court documents, we extract information
concerning the filers’ financial and demographic information at the time of filing and the final
outcome of their cases. Specifically, we collect data on the outcomes predicted by our model:
the choice of plan length, whether the plan is confirmed or not, whether the case is successfully
completed or not, and the recovery rate of the creditors.3In addition to these endogenous
outcomes, in our model, the decision to file for Chapter 13 in the first place is also endogenous.
Although all the debtors in our sample have chosen to file for Chapter 13, we identify the
parameters associated with this decision through the variation in the decision to continue or
voluntarily default on the plan following the shocks to financial conditions.
2Excess income is income minus necessary expenses including housing payments either in the form of rent or in the
form of mortgages. Note that the mortgage debt that is not yet due is paid outside the Chapter 13 repayment plan.
3Throughout the article, by recovery rate of the creditors, we mean their recovery within Chapter 13. It is possible
that the creditors collect payments outside Chapter 13 as well. We return to this possibility in Section 7.3.
AN ANATOMY OF U.S.PERSONAL BANKRUPTCY UNDER CHAPTER 13 673
We estimate our model using the maximum likelihood approach. Our estimates confirm
that the debtor’s choice of plan length indeed affects the trustee’s opinions on the fairness and
feasibility of the plan. In particular, after controlling for exogenous debtor characteristics, we
find that longer plans are more likely to be confirmed in the first place and less likely to be
dismissed after the original plan becomes infeasible. However, whether a debtor’s income is
above the state median level does not play a significant role in the confirmation of the plan.4As
such, the means test established under BAPCPA appears inconsequential. In addition, we find
that the timing of the changes in debtors’ conditions during bankruptcy plays a significant role
in governing Chapter 13 outcomes, including the ability of debtors to obtain a financial fresh
start. In particular, when negative shocks to income are experienced early in the program, the
probability of dismissal rises significantly.
We next conduct policy experiments to assess the effect of section 1325, paragraph 4, which
was added to the U.S. Bankruptcy Code under BAPCPA. This policy imposes additional
restrictions on the length of payment plans for debtors with income above the state median.
Our results predict that this new policy would not materially affect creditor recovery rates
and would not necessarily make discharge more likely for debtors with income above the
state median. This finding is robust to alternative policy experiments that require bankruptcy
plans to meet stricter standards in other ways, such as proposing a higher recovery rate. In
fact, in these alternative experiments, some Chapter 13 filers no longer choose to file, with the
result that recovery rates and discharge rates even decline. It appears therefore that a stricter
bankruptcy code can make it more difficult for debtors to obtain a fresh start but without
necessarily helping to raise creditor recovery rates.
It is well understood that personal bankruptcy laws affect credit markets and therefore the
supply and demand for credit (Gropp et al., 1997; Lin and White, 2001), the ability of households
to insure against labor income risk (Athreya et al., 2012), their consumption behavior (Grant,
2004; Filer and Fisher, 2005), labor supply (Han and Li, 2007), mobility (Elul and Subramanian,
2002), and entrepreneurial activity (Meh and Terajima, 2008; Mankart and Rodano, 2015).
Given that the effect of the personal bankruptcy laws on these economic outcomes is through
the decision to file for bankruptcy in the first place, it is important to understand the determi-
nants of households’ bankruptcy and default decisions. In early work, Domowitz and Sartain
(1999) use a nested logit model to estimate consumers’ decisions to file for bankruptcy and
their choice of bankruptcy chapter but they take a reduced-form approach for values of each
of these decisions. Gross and Souleles (2002) estimate a dynamic probit model of default using
individuals’ credit card account data and conclude that the increase in the bankruptcy filing
rates between 1995 and 1997 cannot be explained by risk factors and economic conditions alone.
In their analysis, they do not distinguish between different default options. Using data from the
Panel Study of Income Dynamics Fay et al. (2002) test whether households are more likely to
file for bankruptcy if the financial benefits from filing for bankruptcy are higher. They compute
the financial benefits from filing for bankruptcy using the Chapter 7 bankruptcy alternative
alone. Our article contributes to the literature on household bankruptcy default decisions5and
complements these papers by endogenizing the value of the Chapter 13 bankruptcy alternative
using a structural model that explicitly takes into account the choices made by the debtors
within Chapter 13 and the uncertainties they face.6Moreover, by considering the particular
channels through which observable and unobservable debtor characteristics affect bankruptcy
outcomes, we are able to provide an assessment on how changes in bankruptcy law might alter
the outcomes in Chapter 13 and therefore the value of filing for Chapter 13.
4Whether income is above the state median appears immaterial for the confirmation of the plan; however, income
plays an important role through the determination of excess income and therefore the required plan payments.
5There are also related studies looking at bankruptcy filings at the state level. See, for example, Dick and Lehnert
(2010), Cornwell and Xu (2014), and Gross et al. (2014).
6See Eckstein and Wolpin (1989), Rust (1996), Aguirregabiria and Mira (2010), and Keane et al. (2011) for surveys
of structural dynamic choice models.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT