What Does Rebalancing Really Achieve?

Published date01 July 2016
Date01 July 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1545
WHAT DOES REBALANCING REALLY ACHIEVE?
KEITH CUTHBERTSON
,
*, SIMON HAYLEY, NICK MOTSON and DIRK NITZSCHE
Cass Business School, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK
ABSTRACT
There is now a substantial literature on the effects of rebalancing on portfolio performance. However, this literature contains
frequent misattribution between rebalancing returns, which are specic to the act of rebalancing, and diversication returns,
which can be earned by both rebalanced and unrebalanced strategies. Confusion on this issue can encourage investors to follow
strategies that involve insufcient diversication and excessive transactions costs. This paper identies the misleading claims
that are made for rebalanced strategies and demonstrates in theory and by simulation that the apparent advantages of rebalanced
strategies over innite horizons give an inaccurate impression of their performance over nite horizons. Copyright © 2016 John
Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
Received 16 November 2015; Accepted 17 November 2015
JEL CODE: G10; G11
KEY WORDS: Rebalancing; diversication returns; excess growth; volatility pumping
1. INTRODUCTION
Rebalancing is a vital part of many investment strategies. Passive strategies usually involve choosing portfolio
weights according to some predetermined rule, and a key practical element of such strategies is the frequency
and hence cost of rebalancing. Only if portfolio weights are allowed to evolve over time according to the relative
returns on the component assets (a buy and hold strategy, B&H) will there be no rebalancing. Other passive strat-
egies require at least periodic rebalancing, and in the extreme, some passive strategies assume continuous
rebalancing to keep asset weights constant (an assumption that is often required to produce tractable closed form
results). Rebalancing is so widespread that a good understanding of its effects is vital.
The well-established literature on optimal growth considers portfolio weights chosen to maximize the ex-
pected geometric growth rate of the portfolio value, consistent with maximizing the expected logarithm of
nal wealth (Kelly, 1956; Luenberger, 1997; Thorp, 2010; Platen and Rendek, 2010). Rebalancing is a vital
part of these strategies. Another strand of the literature considers arbitrary xed weight portfolios, which are
compared with a B&H strategy (e.g. Fernholz and Shay, 1982; Booth and Fama, 1992; Luenberger, 1997;
Mulvey et al., 2007; Qian, 2012; Willenbrock, 2011). A key result from this part of the literature is that a
rebalanced portfolio of independently and identically distributed (IID) assets has a higher expected portfolio
growth rate than the corresponding B&H strategy even when assets follow a random walk. Volatility
pumpingis a strategy that seeks to boost this effect by deliberately choosing high volatility assets and
rebalancing each period to xed weights.
In this paper, we focus on the choice between constant portfolio weight rebalanced strategies and the corre-
sponding B&H strategies. We examine under what circumstances and for what reasons one strategy outperforms
the other. The purpose of this paper is to correct misleading claims that are widely made about the benets of
rebalancing.
*Correspondence to: Simon Hayley, Cass Business School, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, UK. E-mail: simon.hayley.1@city.ac.uk
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd.
International Journal of Finance & Economics
Int. J. Fin. Econ. 21: 224240 (2016)
Published online 17 February 2016 in Wiley Online Library
(wileyonlinelibrary.com). DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1545
It is widely noted that even when there is no predictable time structure to asset returns, rebalanced portfolios
generate excess growth(dened in this literature as expected geometric portfolio growth which is greater than
the average geometric growth of the underlying assets). We demonstrate mathematically that unrebalanced portfo-
lios also generate excess growthand that growth rates of unrebalanced and rebalanced portfolios only diverge to
the extent that drift in portfolio weights gradually leaves the unrebalanced portfolio less well diversied.
Confusion on this issue appears to have arisen in part because of the difculty in making meaningful com-
parisons between rebalanced and unrebalanced portfolios, because even when the portfolios are initially iden-
tical, the composition of the unrebalanced portfolio tends to shift over time. We derive like-for-like
comparisons between rebalanced and unrebalanced portfolios and demonstrate analytically that in the absence
of mean reversion in relative asset prices, the greater expected growth of rebalanced strategies is entirely ex-
plained by their lower portfolio volatilities rather than as is claimed being due to the rebalancing trades
themselves being protable. We also demonstrate that the apparent advantages of such rebalanced strategies
over innite horizons are very misleading indicators of performance over the nite horizons that are likely to
be of interest to investors.
This has important implications for investors. The misleading claims that are made for rebalancing encourage
investors to increase the scale of their rebalancing trades by holding volatile assets and rebalancing frequently.
More efcient portfolios can be constructed simply by diversifying effectively. Investors might rationally prefer
rebalancing strategies where they anticipate mean reversion in relative asset prices, but this is very different from
the claims in the theoretical literature that rebalancing directly boosts returns even in the absence of any such time
structure in returns.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the theoretical and empirical literature
on rebalancing. Section 3 shows, using analytic and simulation approaches, that under standard assump-
tions, the expected growth rate of a portfolio of risky assets (either rebalanced or B&H) is entirely ex-
plained by diversication, with no additional rebalancing return. Section 4 examines the impact o f
rebalancing in the widely cited case of a portfolio consisting of one risky and one risk-free asset. Conclu-
sions are drawn in Section 5.
2. LITERATURE REVIEW
Rebalancing is important in a wide range of situations. It is inherent in any portfolio-weighting strategy other than
capitalization-weighting and plays a part in the debate over fundamental and alternative forms of equity indexing
(Arnott et al., 2005; Kaplan, 2008; Hsu et al., 2011) and universal portfolios (Cover, 1991). Rebalancing also has a
signicant impact on the growth rates of portfolios of commodity futures (Gorton and Rouwenhorst, 2006a and
2006b; Erb and Harvey 2006).
In the theoretical literature, Cheng and Deets (1971) compare the performance of B&H and rebalancing
strategies, assuming that risky asset prices follow random walks and are IID except for their different mean
returns μ
i
. The B&H strategy and the rebalancing strategy give the same expected terminal wealth when
the mean returns of all risky assets are equal. However, if at least one pair of assets has different mean
returns μ
i
μ
j
, then an initially equally weighted B&H strategy always gives a higher expected terminal
wealth than the corresponding rebalancing strategy (intuitively, a B&H portfolio is likely over time to give
increasing weight to the assets with higher μ
i
). This relative superiority of B&H in terms of expected
wealth is found to be larger the greater the dispersion of the μ
i
, the longer the investment horizon and
the more frequently the rebalanced portfolio is returned to equal weights.
A specic situation that is widely analysed (e.g. Fernholz and Shay, 1982; Perold and Sharpe, 1988;
Luenberger, 1997; Gabay and Herlemont, 2007) is a portfolio that is rebalanced each period to keep a xed pro-
portion 1 πin a risk-free asset that pays zero interest. The remainder is invested in a risky asset that follows
the lognormal diffusion process S
t
= exp(gt +σW(t)), where g=μσ
2
/2 and W(t) is a Wiener process.
Hence, if g= 0, the long-term growth rate of this risky asset approaches zero as t
.
However, the terminal wealth
of the rebalanced portfolio is
WHAT DOES REBALANCING REALLY ACHIEVE?225
Copyright © 2016 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Int. J. Fin. Econ. 21: 224240 (2016)
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT