Tribute to Marcus Berliant: A pivotal matchmaker of general equilibrium and spatial economics

Published date01 March 2020
Date01 March 2020
AuthorPing Wang,Masahisa Fujita
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12240
Int J Econ Theory. 2020;16:626.wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijet6
|
© 2019 IAET
Received: 22 February 2019
|
Accepted: 17 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/ijet.12240
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Tribute to Marcus Berliant: A pivotal
matchmaker of general equilibrium and
spatial economics
Masahisa Fujita
1
|
Ping Wang
2,3
1
Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto
University, Kyoto, Japan
2
Department of Economics, Washington
University, St. Louis, Missouri
3
National Bureau of Economic Research
(NBER), Cambridge, Massachusetts
Correspondence
Institute of Economic Research, Kyoto
University, Sakyoku, YoshidaHonmachi,
Kyoto 6068501, Japan.
Email: fujita@kier.kyoto-u.ac.jp
Abstract
We review fundamental contributions by Marcus
Berliant, with a view to a way forward. We focus on
two themes to which he has contributed significantly:
general equilibrium theory with land and location and
general equilibrium analysis of spatial agglomeration.
KEYWORDS
general equilibrium, land, local public goods, location theory, spatial
agglomeration, spatial economics, urban economics
JEL CLASSIFICATION
D50; D60; H41; O41; R13
1
|
INTRODUCTION
As is well known, Marcus Berliant has made fundamental contributions to urban economics
and spatial economics over the four decades of his academic career to date. As old friends and
collaborators of Marcus, we are pleased to have this opportunity to write about Marcus's work
and its impact. From the viewpoint of colleagues in urban economics and spatial economics,
Marcus has been unique as a master of modern general equilibrium theory.
In 1982, under the supervision of Professor Gérard Debreu at the University of California,
Berkeley, Marcus completed his PhD dissertation, A General Equilibrium Model of an Economy
with Land. Then he started his academic career as a general equilibrium theorist mainly in th e
fields of urban economics, spatial economics, and public economics. Since then, as a researcher in
these fields, he makes an invaluable contribution to their further development by not only offering
frank critiques on existing models but also creating new original approaches.
As will be explainedlater, in Berliant et al. (2006b) and Berliant and Fujita (2008) we described
the knowledge exchange and creation process as a selective match and a square dance.Inthis
respect, we (Fujita and Wang) are very lucky to have been able to participate in matching and
dancing with Marcus. We are indeed not alone during his square dancing, Marcus has been
rotating with many partners, including another guest editor of this issue (Peng) as well as several
of his 38 PhD advisees.
In the remainder of this tribute, we focus on the two themes, land in general equilibrium and
spatial agglomeration in general equilibrium, and highlight with a view to a way forward what
Marcus has achieved through his matching and square dancing over the past four decades.
Because of the mathematical complexity of the former theme, we will provide some necessary
mathematical illustrations. Throughout the tribute, we will leave out further details but refer
the reader to the original papers as specified in various footnotes.
1
2
|
LAND IN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM
Marcus has worked tirelessly in developing a sounder mathematical basis for microeconomics
with land. In this section we highlight his fundamental contribution to general equilibrium
theory with land and location.
2.1
|
Land and economic theory
Land is everywhere, providing the foundation for our existence. In addition, the spatial extent of
land is accompanied by the dual concept of location in human activity. Together, land and
location are essential ingredients for individual life as well as for national economies. Yet, it is
rare to find an economics text in which land and location, or space, are studied as an important
subject if they are even mentioned.
The reason for such neglect of land and location in mainstream economics is not entirely
clear. In the following discussion, however, we concur with Marcus's observation that the set of
unique characteristics of land makes it difficult, conceptually as well as mathematically, to
incorporate land into the traditional framework of general equilibrium theory. To understand
the unique characteristics of land and the causes of such difficulties, we refer to Table 1, which
categorizes the possible types of general equilibrium framework or model in terms of the
number of agents and the number of commodities.
Starting with the classic ArrowDebreu economy in the northwest block, let us recall that in
their seminal article Arrow and Debreu (1954) defined each commodity by its physical
characteristics as well as by the location (and date) at which it is available. Hence, once we have
thus indexed commodities properly, land becomes just another good in the ArrowDebreu
economy. As emphasized by Hildenbrand (1974, pp. 8384), however, the introduction of the
location (and date) of availability in defining a commodity has its drawbacks, which arise when
examining the assumptions that are needed to demonstrate the existence of an equilibrium. In
particular, Schweizer et al. (1976) point out that the convexity of preferences makes little sense,
as it implies that consumers would desire to own land that is spread out rather than
concentrated.
As is well known, one useful way to attack such problems is to use the convexifying effect of
large numbers of agents when there are a finite number of commodities. That is, moving to the
1
The reader is also referred to review articles by us, Berliant and Wang (2019), in the Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance.
FUJITA AND WANG
|
7

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT