Trade liberalization, forward‐looking firms, and welfare

Date01 November 2017
Published date01 November 2017
AuthorKuo‐Feng Kao,Cheng‐Hau Peng
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12293
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Trade liberalization, forward-looking firms, and
welfare
Kuo-Feng Kao
1
|
Cheng-Hau Peng
2
1
Tamkang University, New Taipei City,
Taiwan
2
Fu Jen Catholic University, New Taipei
City, Taiwan
Correspondence
Cheng-Hau Peng, Department of Eco-
nomics, Fu Jen Catholic University, No.
510, Zhongzheng Rd, Xinzhuang Dis-
trict, New Taipei City 24205, Taiwan.
Email: chpon@mail.fju.edu.tw
JEL Classification: F12, F13
Abstract
We set up an oligopolistic model with two exporting firms
selling to a third market to investigate the welfare implica-
tions of trade liberalization when the exporting firms are
forward-looking. The results show that with cost asymmetry
trade liberalization encourages the exporting firms to engage
in tacit collusion, which may not only be detrimental to the
domestic welfare, but also to the consumer surplus of the
importing country. Moreover, we find that tacit collusion is
less sustainable if the government of the importing country
imposes a lower (higher) tariff on the more (less) efficient
exporting firm. If a nonforward-looking or a forward-
looking cost-efficient domestic firm exists in the importing
country, then trade liberalization also encourages tacit
collusion.
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Tariff protection has always been criticized as a policy that makes domestic consumers worse off by
forcing them to pay higher prices for imports. Therefore, if firms behave noncollusively, it is com-
monly believed that trade liberalization will favor consumers in importing countries owing to the more
intense rivalry between firms. This pro-competition effect may well characterize the reality in some
industries. In other industries, firms may have incentives to engage in tacit collusion.
In their empirical survey, Blume, Strand, and Färnstrand (2002) find that trade liberalization indu-
ces tacit collusion among exporting firms in European Union (E.U.) sugar markets. Bond and Syropou-
los (2008) also suggest a possible linkage between trade liberalization and international cartels. In
addition, the European Commission has reported cartel statistics from 1990 to 2014 in the European
Union.
1
We summarize these statistics in Table 1. The table shows that the number of cartel cases
increased significantly since 2000. Nevertheless, data compiled by the World Bank show that the
weighted mean applied tariff of manufactured products in the European Union was around 6 percent in
1990 but later dropped to 2 percent in 2000 and was steadily around 2 percent after 2000.
2
Although
Rev Int Econ. 2017;25:9991016. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie V
C2017 JohnWiley & Sons Ltd
|
999
Received: 10 January 2014
|
Revised: 2 December 2016
|
Accepted: 10 March 2017
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12293
this provides no direct evidence of a causal relationship between trade liberalization and tacit collusion,
it seems to be appropriate to investigate the possibility of such a relationship.
We also observe that some exporting firms have fixed or raised their export prices despite the
fact that trade costs have been gradually decreasing around the world. One example is the dynamic
random access memo ry (DRAM) industry i n the European Unio n. Micron was the firs t to squeal
on the rest of the cartel. In 2010, the European Commission fined 10 chipmakers (including Nanya
and Samsung) a total of e331.3 million for keeping the prices of DRAM artificially high between
1998 and 2002 by sharing secret informationamong themselves. A second example is that
involving Unilever and P&G who in 2011 were fined a total of e315.2 million by the European
Commission for agreeing with Henkel KGaA, the German maker of Persil, to fix the prices of the
detergent in eight countries over a 3-year period.
3
These observations motivate us to investigate
how an importing co untrys trade liberalization affects the incentives of exporting firms to collude
when selling to that market.
In this paper, we employ an oligopolistic setting with two exporting firms selling to an importing
country that lowers its tariffs.
4
The results show that trade liberalization encourages the forward-
looking exporting firms to engage in tacit collusion. This tacit collusion may raise the market price in
the third country, which is pernicious to its consumers and welfare. Such a result is robust regardless
of the competition mode of the firms, the existence of a domestic competitor, and whether the import-
ing country adopts the most favored nation clause (MFN, i.e., a uniform tariff) or discriminatory
tariffs.
This paper is closely related to the literature on the nexus between trade policies and the collusive
behavior of firms in repeated games. Most studies in this strand of the literature consider an intra-
industry model with firms selling a homogeneous product based on the framework of Brander and
Krugman (1983).
5
Examples are Pinto (1986), Schultz (2002), Haufler and Schjelderup (2004), and
Bond and Syropoulos (2008), among others. Pinto (1986) extends Brander and Krugman (1983) by
considering repeated interactions among quantity-setting firms in both their domestic and export mar-
kets. He finds that if trade costs are negligible, no exports result in a strong Nash equilibrium for the
two colluding firms. Schultz (2002) investigates the incentives for identical domestic firms to collude
in an export cartel. He shows that the formation of an export cartel improves the monitoring of collu-
sion, thereby shortening the time needed to detect the deviation. In addition, when the production tech-
nology of firms exhibits constant returns to scale, this will lead to firms that deviate being subject to
greater punishment and result in the collusion becoming more stable. Haufler and Schjelderup (2004)
analyze the effects of international commodity tax policies on the stability of collusive agreements
between firms, and also find that reducing the tax stabilizes the collusion among firms. Bond and Syro-
poulos (2008) show that the relationship between collusive conduct and trade costs may be nonmono-
tonic depending on the magnitude of the trade costs. Furthermore, if trade costs are below the
threshold level, trade liberalization may reduce total output and lower welfare.
In a departure from the above-mentioned papers, we consider a three-country exporting model sim-
ilar to the models in Brander and Spencer (1985), Gatsios (1990) and Hwang and Mai (1991), and
assume that exporting firms produce differentiated products with different marginal costs. Brander and
TABLE 1 Cartel statistics in the European Union
19901994 19951999 20002004 20052009 20102014
No. of cases 10 10 30 33 30
Amount of nes (e) 344,282,550 270,963,500 3,157,348,710 7,920,497,226 7,613,104,579
1000
|
KAO AND PENG

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT