Timing of entry and location/product differentiation

Published date01 June 2018
Date01 June 2018
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12151
AuthorChia‐Hung Sun
Timing of entry and location/product differentiation
Chia-Hung Sun
This research considers two alternative timing games, the precommitment game and the
preemption game, where duopoly firms choose their respective timing of market entry and post-
entry profits are generated by price competition in a spatial modelalaHotelling (1929). We find
that the time of first entry is increasing and the time of second entry is decreasing in location
differentiation. The results are robust and valid both from an equilibrium analysis and from a
welfare analysis. We also note that the difference in equilibrium entry times is too close from the
viewpoint of social welfare.
Key words Hotelling model, precommitment game, preemption game, timing game
JEL classification L13, D21, R10, O30
Accepted 13 January 2017
1 Introduction
Without a doubt, time and space, combined into space-time, are very important in everyday life. The
spatial economics literature presents findings on the impact of space on an agent’s economic
decisions, compared to the analysis from non-spatial economics. Conversely, the timing games
literature investigates the issue of a firm’s timing decision on market entry, with the model of a
timing game mostly based on a non-spatial context. The present study contributes further to the
analysis of spatial issues in the related literature by examining a timing game of entry under a spatial
market.
The purpose of this study is to examine how location differentiation affects firms’ timing of entry
into a market. We assume that duopoly firms are exogenously symmetrically located in a Hotelling
(1929) linear city. The two first decide whether and when to enter the market and then compete on
price in the product market. We explore the equilibrium outcomes both when the firms can
precommit to their timing of entry the so-called precommitment game proposed by Reinganum
(1981a, b) and when they are flexible in altering their timing of entry the so-called preemption
game offered by Fudenberg and Tirole (1985). We also illustrate welfare analysis by investigating the
optimal timing of entry and compare the private and social incentives for market entry.
In reality there are some commonly observed ‘‘stylized facts’’ for market entry timing. First, there
is an initial delay of entry into a new market (new technology entry). Second, there are differences in
the adoption and diffusion rates of the timing of new technology entry among firms in the same
industry as well as across industry sectors. In some industries, once the initial adoption of new
technology occurs, the remaining firms utilize the new technology at an accelerating pace. In
Department of Economics, Soochow University, Taipei, Taiwan. Email: jerry52.sun@msa.hinet.net
Financial support from the Ministry of Science and Technology (103-2410-H-031-010) is deeply appreciated.
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12151
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 179–200 ©IAET 179
International Journal of Economic Theory
contrast, in some industries the initial adoption of new technology undergoes a decelerating
adoption process.
1
It is well known that if geographical space is seen as a product space, then a spatial model is also
able to explain product locations, and our analysis can be extended to the context of a product
differentiation model. In this case, location differentiation denotes the degree of product
substitutability, and smaller location differentiation corresponds to more competitive pressure. Our
analysis can thus be applied to investigate how the timing of entry differs across industries with
different degrees of competitive pressure. As will be shown, greater location differentiation (i.e. less
fierce competition) helps explain the stylized facts of delaying first entry as well as the accelerating
process in technology adoption.
This study is related to the timing games literature with strategic interaction in the product
market. A pioneering work in this literature is Reinganum (1981a, b), who uses a game-theoretic
approach with unobservable actions between players to investigate firms’ incentives to adopt a new
technology.
2
Reinganum (1981a, b) assumes that firms can precommit to their timing of technology
adoption at the beginning of the game and shows that the model has a unique Nash equilibrium, in
which the equilibrium involves sequential adoption with higher payoffs for the first mover (i.e. a new
technology is diffused over time and there is a first-mover advantage). The precommitment game
captures the idea that the costs of altering the adoption plans are prohibitively high or there are
infinitely long information lags.
Based on a precommitment game, Lippman and Mamer (1993) investigate the case where only
one firm can adopt the new technology (i.e. winner takes all). Some approaches deal with uncertainty
and rivalry in the product market. For instance, Stenbacka and Tombak (1994) and Gotz (2000)
extend the model of Reinganum (1981a, b) by assuming that the length of time required for
successful implementation is uncertain.
The preemption game, based on Fudenberg and Tirole (1985), captures the idea that firms can
observe their rivals’ adoptions and are flexible in altering their timing of entry, but they cannot
credibly commit to maintaining their timing of entry. This could occur because the costs of altering
adoption plans are not significant or the information lags are negligible. Fudenberg and Tirole
(1985) show that a potential advantage from being first is the introduction of an incentive for
preempting rival firms, thus speeding up the time at being the first to adopt a new technology, until
payoffs are the same for both firms (i.e. rent equalization).
3
For subsequent applications, Hendricks (1992) finds that uncertainty about the innovative
capabilities of the rival firm tends to slow down the first adoption of a new technology in the
preemption game. Riordan (1992) notes that regulation schemes may slow adoption by making
preemptivestrategies less attractive. Riordan and Salant(1994) consider strategic technology adoption
1
Hoppe (2002) and Milliou and Petrakis (2011) introduce some examples of the initial delay in new technology adoption:
the adoptions of computer-aided design (CAD), the basic oxygen furnace (BOF), and computer numerically controlled
(CNC) machine tools. On the other hand, the adoption and diffusion rates of information and communication
technology (ICT) differ across industry sectors. See Griliches (1957), Mansfield (1985), and Asterbo (2002) for detailed
discussions.
2
On the other hand, some literature contributions deal with uncertainty regarding the value of a new technology, but no
strategic interaction in the product market is considered. See, among others, Jensen (1988), Kapur (1995), and Vettas
(1998).
3
The mechanism at work is as follows. As a result of the potentially higher payoffs for the leader than for the follower, the
follower can profitably deviate to adopt the new technology just before the leader does. The leader anticipates this and
adopts the new technology at an earlier time so that the follower is indifferent between adopting just before or much after
that time. Consequently, the potential early-mover advantage stimulates preemption, until payoffs are equalized for both
firms.
Timing of entry Chia-Hung Sun
180 International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 179–200 ©IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT