The size premium and macrovolatility risks: Evidence from U.S. and U.K. equity markets

Published date01 July 2019
AuthorSungjun Cho
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1717
Date01 July 2019
Received: 14 June 2016 Revised: 11 December 2018 Accepted: 4 January 2019
DOI: 10.1002/ijfe.1717
RESEARCH ARTICLE
The size premium and macrovolatility risks: Evidence from
U.S. and U.K. equity markets
Sungjun Cho
Alliance Manchester Business School,
Crawford House, University of
Manchester, Oxford Road,Manchester
M13 9PL, UK
Correspondence
Sungjun Cho, Alliance Manchester
Business School, Crawford House,
University of Manchester, Oxford Road,
Manchester M13 9PL, UK.
Email: sungjun.cho@mbs.ac.uk
JEL Classification: E32; E52; G12
Abstract
The size effect is alive well but visible only when the economy is in high volatil-
ity regimes. This paper develops variant conditional asset pricing tests for the
size effect with independent business cycle and volatility regimes and shows that
the size effect is present conditionally during the high-volatility regimes. This
result is robust across two countries (United States and United Kingdom) with
various specifications and the January effect. An economic rationale for the rela-
tion between the size premium and macrovolatility risk is provided through the
capital-market-imperfection hypothesis.
KEYWORDS
capital-market imperfections, great moderation, the size premium, volatility-regime switching
1INTRODUCTION
Banz (1981) first reports that small-capitalization firms
on the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) earned higher
average returns than is predicted by the CAPM from 1936
to 1975. Fama and French (1993) adopt this empirical
fact and develop their three-factor asset pricing model
with the market excess return (RMRF) and two mim-
icking portfolios based on market capitalization (SMB)
and book-to-market (HML). The Fama–French model has
become an industry standard because it can explain the
averagereturn variations across portfolios formed on many
different characteristics. Fama and French interpret their
two mimicking portfolios as risk factors capturing a risk
premium for the relative distress of firms in the context
of ICAPM while the underlying economic source of the
risk premium has not yet fully understood. Further, the
same empirical findings are documented with interna-
tional data, and as a result, international Fama–French
three-factor models are developed (see for instance,
Griffin, 2002; Bekaert, Hodrick, & Zhang, 2009).
van Dijk (2011) surveys the literature on the size effect
and identifies two seemingly contradictory developments
in research since the late 1990s; many theoretical models
are developed to explain the size effect (e.g., Berk, Green,
& Naik, 1999), but most of the empirical studies find that
the size effect has disappeared since the early 1980s. For
example, Horowitz, Loughran, and Savin (2000) report
that U.S. small firms did not earn higher average realized
returns than big firms after its discovery in 1980, and Dim-
son and Marsh (1999) find the similar phenomenon for the
U.K. data. Schwert (2003) asserts that “it seems that the
small-firm anomaly has disappeared since the initial pub-
lication of the papers that discovered it." It is well known
that if the anomalies are a result of data-snooping bias,
these are expected to disappear in the data soon after they
have been reported. If this is indeed the case, the SMB
factor may not be interpreted as a systematic risk factor
to generate a risk premium in the rational-asset-pricing
model.
Interestingly, Hou and van Dijk (2010) argue that the
size effect exists in ex ante expected returns but might
not be visible in realized returns. They show that small
firms experience large negative profitability shocks after
the early 1980s, while big firms experience large positive
shocks. After filtering out this noise, they find a robust
Int J Fin Econ. 2019;24:1271–1286. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe ©2019 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 1271
1272 CHO
size effect in expected returns and ask for a revival of aca-
demic research on the size effect. Based on the careful
summary of the literature, van Dijk (2011) (p. 3263) also
argues “it is premature to conclude that the size effect has
gone away...whether and how existing models can be rec-
onciled with known patterns in the returns on small and
large stocks is not clear." Finally Fama and French (2015)
show the evidence for the size effect in U.S. market using
their five-factor model.
This paper documents a new stylized fact on the size
effect to resolve this seemingly puzzling issue. Specifically,
motivated by Lettau, Ludvigson, and Wachter (2008),
this paper develops conditional asset pricing tests using
regime-switching models for the growth rate of U.S.indus-
trial production and the U.S. or U.K. size premium. As
a result, mean and volatility regimes are separately iden-
tified. The estimated mean regimes are closely tracking
business-cycle patterns, and the volatility regimes pick
up the so-called great moderation from 1984 to 2007.
While it is often said that recessions coincides with the
high-volatility regimes, the correlation of two regimes in
United States are moderate (e.g., 0.26 since July 1963).
The empirical findings from these conditional tests
unequivocally indicate that the U.S. or U.K. SMB factor
earns a significant risk premium only in uncertain macroe-
conomic states (measured as high-volatility regimes of
industrial production growth), even though it has almost
zero risk premium unconditionally. This new stylized fact
on the relation between the size premium and macro-
volatility risks is quite robust across various specifica-
tions and with the January effect. Arguably, the so-called
“Great Moderation"coined by Ben Bernanke (or low macro
volatility regimes) has effectively masked the size effect
until recently. Kim and Nelson (1999) and McConnell
and Perez-Quiros (2000) show that U.S. output volatility
had declined substantially in the early 1980s. This period
coincides with the initial publication of the size effect.
However, the size effect has been resurrected since the
recent financial crisis coupled with uncertain economic
environment. For example, the average monthly size pre-
mium for US was 1.615% during 2008.
Interestingly, recent empirical asset-pricing studies also
emphasize the role of macroeconomic volatility move-
ments in determining risk premia. For example, Boguth
and Kuehn (2013) show that time variation in consump-
tion volatility is a negatively priced source of risk for vari-
ous test portfolios. Bansal, Kiku, Shaliastovich, and Yaron
(2014) also find that macroeconomic volatility risks (mea-
sured as realized variance of industrial production growth)
carry a sizeable positive risk premium and help explain
the cross-section of expected equity returns. Further, the
empirical findings of this paper suggest that the changing
macroeconomic volatility has an important implication
on the changing size premium. While it is not yet fully
understood why macrovolatility risks are important for
understanding risk premia, we have one good theoretical
explanation on the size premium. Perez-Quiros and Tim-
mermann (2000), based on the imperfect capital-market
theories, claim that small firms with little collateral do
not have the same access to credit markets that are
enjoyed by large firms and argue that the high returns to
small firms (SMB) might be compensation for taking this
credit-related risk because small firms are more affected
by tight-credit market conditions interpreted as recession
periods.
Perhaps, in well-developed U.S. and U.K.financial mar-
kets, recession itself would not hamper raising capitals
for the small-sized firms unless it coincides with the
high uncertainty. While the lack of data makes it diffi-
cult to test this hypothesis directly, there are some indi-
rect evidence to support this line of arguments. First,
using OECD data, Mendicino (2007) documents a nega-
tive and significant relation between credit market size
(financial depth) and the volatility of output, consump-
tion, investment, investment in residential properties, and
housing prices. Tang and Yan (2010) find that average
credit-default swap (CDS) spreads are increasing in gross
domestic product (GDP) growth volatility. Further, Baum,
Caglayan, and Ozkan (2009) report the potentially adverse
effects of macroeconomic volatility on the allocation of
banks' lending behavior. This adverse effects would affect
small firms significantly because small firms are more
dependent on bank loans while large firms have bet-
ter access to direct sources of credit such as commer-
cial paper (e.g., Gertler & Gilchrist, 1994). Finally the
credit crunch induced by higher macroeconomic volatil-
ity could hit small firms with less collateral the hardest
while larger firms were less affected by renegotiating their
loans or using commercial paper or corporate bonds (e.g.,
Holmstrom & Tirole, 1997).
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section
2 discusses the empirical models; Section 3 describes the
data; Section 4 presents the estimation results; and Section
5 concludes.
2EMPIRICAL MODELS
This section develops empirical methods used to test the
existence of the size premium; the first subsection briefly
describes a regime-switching model with mean and volatil-
ity regimes for the U.S. industrial-production growth, and
the second subsection explains how to test whether a factor
is redundant unconditionally. The third subsection com-
bines these two models and presents the main econometric
specifications for conditional asset pricing tests.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT