The Legal and the Social in Romano's Institutionalism

Published date01 June 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/raju.12290
Date01 June 2020
AuthorPablo Marshall
© (2020) John Wiley & Sons Ltd.
Ratio Juris. Vol. 33 No. 2 June 2020 (258–263)
The Legal and the Social in
Romano’s Institutionalism
PABLO MARSHALL
1. Introduction
Santi Romano’s The Legal Order (2017) is part of the tradition of legal institutionalism.
The first warning that must be provided in that regard is that Romano’s legal institu-
tionalism should not be confused with theories of other authors who can also be con-
sidered legal institutionalists. This includes, for example, those who are interested in
the idea that law is composed of what the philosopher John Searle (1969) called insti-
tutional facts, that is to say, facts whose meaning depends on norms (setting them in
opposition to brute facts, whose meaning does not depend on norms). The name of the
Scottish jurist Neil MacCormick (see MacCormick and Weinberger 1986) is inescap-
able when referring to this kind of legal institutionalism. Although comparisons can
be drawn between this latter kind of institutionalism and that of Romano, it is clear
that while this new version focuses on normative assembled institutions, classical
legal institutionalism considers normativity to be derivative of institutions (La Torre
2016). Nor should Romano’s institutionalism be confused with other lines of institu-
tional thought developed in the United States, which are actually methodological ap-
proaches to political science, sociology, and economics.1 These are not, then, legal
forms of institutionalism, although, as is common in the Northern American academy,
these disciplines and approaches have had an important influence in the study of law.
For the case at hand, we can understand institutionalism as a theory of law
emerged at the beginning of the 20th century and developed by a group of academ-
ics from continental Europe. We must remember that that time was tremendously
prolific for legal thought, as the consolidation of industrial capitalism, with the con-
sequent extension of the state apparatus towards the regulation of productive and
social activity, gave rise to a series of intermediate bodies between individuals and
the state, such as industrial corporations or labour unions. This constituted a call to
re-evaluate, rethink, and propose new theories and solutions for the problems gener-
ated by these new phenomena under the prevailing liberal order during the second
half of the 19th century. Among the authors who have traditionally been identified as
institutionalists are Maurice Hariou (2003) and the controversial Carl Schmitt (2004),
who at least during some period of his life moved away from his decisionism to
1 Probably the most famous example of institutional analysis, in this sense, is Acemoglu and
Robinson 2013.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT