The euro exchange rate and Germany's trade surplus

Published date01 March 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/infi.12359
AuthorMarco Ratto,Stefan Hohberger,Lukas Vogel
Date01 March 2020
International Finance. 2020;23:85103. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/infi © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
85
DOI: 10.1111/infi.12359
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The euro exchange rate and Germanys trade
surplus
Stefan Hohberger
1
|
Marco Ratto
1
|
Lukas Vogel
2
1
European Commission, Joint Research
Centre (JRC), Ispra, Italy
2
European Commission, DG ECFIN,
Brussels, Belgium
Correspondence
Lukas Vogel, European Commission, DG
ECFIN, CHAR 14/233, B-1049, Brussels,
Belgium.
Email: lukas.vogel@ec.europa.eu
Abstract
In the context of debates about the euro exchange rates
(EXR) impact on Germanys (DE) trade surplus, we
estimate a multiregion macroeconomic model (19992018)
and provide a counterfactual in which we simulate the
shocks of the estimated model in an alternative setting with
freely floating nominal EXRs. The results suggest a
reduction of the DE trade surplus by up to 1.3% of gross
domestic product (GDP; around 1/4 of the surplus) during
20102015 compared to the data, together with a stronger
real effective EXR (REER). The rest of the euro area (REA)
net exports are more negative (by up to 0.6% of GDP) in
the counterfactual before the EA crisis, but more positive
(by up to 0.4% of GDP) in recent years. Overall, the
counterfactual DE and REA trade balance and REER
trajectories are very similar to the actual paths. Modifying
shock processes in the counterfactual would give rise to
larger differences.
KEYWORDS
euro, exchange rate, Germany, trade balance
JEL CLASSIFICATION
E44; E52; E53; F41
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The causes and consequences of Germanys persistent trade surplus have been a recurrent topic
in European and international macroeconomics in recent history. While attention centred on
the implications of Germany's surplus for imbalances inside the euro area (EA) for many years,
the policy focus has shifted to spillover on nonEA economies and global implications more
recently. Peter Navarro, for example, argued that German net exports benefit from an
undervalued euro (Financial Times, January 31, 2017). Linking the trade surplus to euro
membership, the view suggests that German net exports might have been lower without the
euro in recent years.
The undervaluationhypothesis has triggered lively debates among economists, with
different views on what the (conjectured) euro weakness meant for German net exports, the EA,
and the rest of the world compared to a hypothetical DMark survival. Münchau (2017) argues
that the critics have a point and that Germany has manipulated its real exchange rate (EXR) by
low wage growth and support for policies that have led to a weaker euro. Fuest (2017) objects
that euro membership should not matter much for the net trade of nonEA economies. He
argues that euro undervaluation for Germany comes with overvaluation for other EA countries,
which implies countervailing effects on EA aggregate exports to and imports from nonEA
economies. Zettelmeyer (2017) makes the complementary point that Germanys persistent trade
surplus is not a structural feature of Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) membership. Real
EXR adjustment in response to shocks and crisis takes longer than in a system of freely floating
nominal EXRs, but it remains possible also with EMU membership. The latter applies at least to
real effective appreciation, whereas depreciation may be complicated by downward nominal
wage rigidity in a lowinflation environment, as argued by Krugman (2017).
This paper contributes to the discussion by presenting a simple counterfactual based on an
estimated openeconomy Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) model. Counterfactual
analysis is a major strength of DSGE models, as discussed, for example, in Coenen, Motto,
Rostagno, Schmidt, and Smets (2017). This class of models provides a framework to study the
impact on shock transmission of selective modifications to equations or parameters that
characterize macroeconomic policy, while keeping the policyinvariant description of household
and firm behaviour unchanged. In this paper, we estimate a version of the European Commissions
Global Multicountry model (GM) with Germany (DE), the rest of the EA (REA), and the rest of the
world (RoW) over the period 1999q12018q4. GM is a structural dynamic macroeconomic (DSGE)
model and is described in detail in Albonico et al. (2019). The model builds on Kollmann et al.
(2016) and is similar to the one in Kollmann, Ratto, Roeger, int Veld, and Vogel (2015), who review
competing hypotheses about the drivers of the DE surplus and assess their quantitative importance.
The model includes a large number of variables and shocks and observables for estimation to
exploit a large amount of timeseries information. The analysis requires a threeregion setup to
account for the fact that DE is a large economy in the EA context, and distinguish between the
intraEA fixed nominal EXR and the floating nominal EXR toward the RoW, with REA and RoW
both being important trading partners for the DE economy.
Estimation of the DSGE model provides values for the model parameters and time profiles for
the shock processes. The counterfactual then reruns the model with the estimated shocks and an
alternative monetary policy setting that imposes a flexible nominal EXR between DE and REA and
policy rules in which the shortterm interest rate in DE responds to DE output and inflation gaps
and the shortterm interest rate in REA responds to REA output and inflation gaps only. The idea of
the counterfactual is similar to Christiano, Motto, and Rostagno (2008) and Sahuc and Smets (2008),
who compare the EA and U.S. economies and assess the role of differences in shocks and structure
for macroeconomic outcomes and the stance of monetary policy.
The simulations suggest that DEs trade balance (TB) surplus would have been lower by up
to 1.3% of gross domestic product (GDP; around 1/4 of the actual surplus) in 20102015,
together with a stronger real effective exchange rate (REER), if DE had had a flexible nominal
EXR instead of being part of the EA. REA TB would have been slightly more negative under a
86
|
HOHBERGER ET AL.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT