The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does residual trade cost bias matter?

AuthorParas Kharel
Date01 February 2019
Published date01 February 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12380
Rev Int Ecom . 2019;27:367–389. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
367
1
|
INTRODUCTION
There has long been an interest among economists and policymakers alike in the effect of regional
trade agreements, or free trade agreements (FTAs), on trade. The proliferation of such agreements
since the early 1990s gave an impetus to empirical investigations.1 As trade agreements continue to be
negotiated, interest in the subject is likely to sustain. The gravity model is the go‐to method for ex post
quantification of FTAs. FTA membership is one of the very few available observable proxies for trade
costs in a gravity equation that is naturally at the bilateral level, varies across bilateral pairs, exhibits
some variation over time and, importantly, is reflective of trade policy.
Received: 12 October 2017
|
Revised: 14 July 2018
|
Accepted: 22 August 2018
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12380
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The effect of free trade agreements revisited: Does
residual trade cost bias matter?
Paras Kharel
South Asia Watch on Trade, Economics and
Environment (SAWTEE), Kathmandu, Nepal
Correspondence
Paras Kharel, South Asia Watch on Trade,
Economics and Environment (SAWTEE),
Baluwatar, Kathmandu, Nepal.
Email: paraskharelpk@gmail.com
JEL Classification
C23, F13, F14, F15
Abstract
This paper revisits a prominent gravity model‐based em-
pirical literature on the effects of free trade agreements by
accounting for a potential bias caused by unobservable
trade costs that operate through general equilibrium con-
straints. It embeds state‐of‐the‐art panel estimation tech-
niques in a recently proposed two‐step remedy that
features a constrained ANOVA‐type estimation. Using a
dataset on manufacturing trade flows in eight sectors in 40
countries and a rest‐of‐the‐world aggregate for the period
1990–2002, it finds evidence of significant residual trade
cost bias. The direction and magnitude of bias vary across
sectors, with the standard one‐step approach used in the
literature overestimating or underestimating the partial ef-
fect of free trade agreements by up to 110 percent. Overall,
coefficients on trade costs variables are jointly signifi-
cantly different between the standard method and the two‐
step method. The biases in partial effect estimates translate
into biases in general equilibrium effects.
368
|
KHAREL
A key concern in estimating the trade effects of FTAs is endogeneity. A traditional source of en-
dogeneity is selection: the existence of unobservables that influence both the signing of FTAs and
trade flows, and the possibility of reverse causality (e.g., country pairs that have a high level of trade
may be entering into FTAs). The literature on the determinants of FTA formation provides robust ev-
idence of the endogeneity of FTAs to trade flows—for example, Baier and Bergstrand (2004), Magee
(2003), Baier, Bergstrand, and Mariutto (2014b) and Bergstrand, Egger, and Larch (2016). A num-
ber of methods have been employed in the literature to deal with such endogeneity concerns. One
approach is to use instrumental variables (IVs). A challenge this approach faces is to find a valid
instrument, that is, a variable that is not only strongly related to the FTA variable but affects the
outcome of interest only through the FTA variable. To avoid relying solely on functional form for
identification in their non‐linear model, Egger, Larch, Staub, and Winkelmann (2011), for example,
use as instruments three dummies denoting whether a country pair has ever had a common colonizer,
has ever been in a colonial relationship and has ever been part of the same country. Another route is
to use matching econometrics, as used by, among others, Baier and Bergstrand (2009a) and Egger,
Egger, and Greenaway (2008). Matching methods assume selection on observables. A third approach
is the use of panel data econometrics. Exploiting panel data on trade flows and FTA formation, papers
in this mold use country‐pair fixed effects to account for pair‐level selection into FTAs, assuming that
time‐varying bilateral unobserved heterogeneity is orthogonal to the FTA variable. Since Baier and
Bergstrand (2007), there has been a wave of empirical studies on the trade effects of FTAs using the
panel estimation approach—for example, Eicher and Henn (2011), Behar and Cirera‐i‐Crivillé (2013),
Dahi and Demir (2013), Baier, Bergstrand, and Feng (2014a), Bergstrand, Larch, and Yotov (2015)
and Anderson and Yotov (2016)—making it the most established method in this line of literature.
A common finding is that FTAs do increase trade substantially, albeit with heterogeneous effects.
Although a variety of methods have been brought to bear on the selection issues around the age‐old
topic of FTA‐trade relationship, an additional source of endogeneity remains ignored. It arises from
the general equilibrium structure of the gravity model, as demonstrated in Egger and Nigai (2015).
In this paper, I show that ignoring this endogeneity substantially biases the effect of FTAs on trade.
To understand the source of this bias, first note that the error term in a panel gravity equation can
be decomposed as a sum of (i) bilateral country‐pair fixed effects, which capture pair‐specific time‐
invariant heterogeneity, including time‐invariant bilateral trade costs; (ii) importer‐year fixed effects;
(iii) exporter‐year fixed effects; and (iv) residual or unobserved trade costs. The inclusion of pair fixed
effects speaks to the traditional endogeneity of FTAs discussed earlier, while the use of exporter‐year
and importer‐year fixed effects controls for multilateral resistance and other country‐time‐specific fac-
tors.2 As Egger and Nigai (2015) show, the country‐time‐specific factors are themselves endogenous
to residual trade costs. In a general gravity context, this endogeneity arises from the market‐clearing
general equilibrium structure underlying a gravity equation. Just as general equilibrium linkages yield
the now well‐appreciated importance of multilateral resistance, the same linkages also imply that the
country‐time‐specific factors are a function of, inter alia, residual trade costs. Egger and Nigai (2015)
demonstrate that this leads to biased estimates of total bilateral trade costs, country‐specific effects
and the partial effects of observable trade cost measures, while also biasing general equilibrium‐con-
sistent comparative statics. They suggest a two‐step remedy to this problem: first obtain unbiased
measures of total trade costs from a constrained ANOVA‐type (CANOVA) estimation of the gravity
model3 and then decompose them into their individual observable components.
To what extent residual trade cost bias is reflected in estimates of FTA effects—arguably the
most prominent policy effect analyzed with a gravity model—is the primary empirical question that
I attempt to answer. In their empirical illustration, Egger and Nigai (2015) take a balanced sample of
manufacturing trade flows in 31 OECD countries for the year 2005 and compare the estimates from

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT