The correlates of international financial‐center status

AuthorNachiket Shah,Barry Eichengreen
Published date01 February 2020
Date01 February 2020
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12441
62
|
wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie Rev Int Econ. 2020;28:62–81.
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
1
|
INTRODUCTION
The geography of international financial centers is very much in play. The United Kingdom’s planned
exit from the European Union raises the question of whether London will maintain its preeminence
and, if not, what other centers might take its place (see, e.g., Brennan, 2018; Roberts, 2018). Chinese
officials have promoted international use of the renminbi with the goal of enhancing Shanghai’s po-
sition as a global financial center, but the success of their efforts remains to be seen (Eichengreen &
Kawai, 2015; Han, 2018). Hong Kong has sought to maintain its role as the leading financial entrepôt
between China and the rest of the world by encouraging mainland companies to list on its stock ex-
change and by establishing a “Stock Connect” through which Chinse investors can purchase shares
(Pan, He, Sigler, Martinus, & Derudder, 2018). European governments and companies meanwhile are
pondering options for relocating financial business away from New York in order to avoid penalties
for noncompliance with U.S. sanctions (Geranmayeh & Batmanghelidj, 2018).1
All this makes it timely to review what we know about international financial‐center status.
Scholars from different disciplines have adopted varying perspectives on this question. Economic
historians such as Cassis (2006) emphasize the importance of historical trade links, historical finan-
cial links, and historical financial development. Economists point in addition to the role of geogra-
phy and technology. They highlight the advantages of a network of information and communications
Received: 4 March 2019
|
Revised: 8 July 2019
|
Accepted: 26 July 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12441
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
The correlates of international financial‐center
status
BarryEichengreen
|
NachiketShah
Department of Economics,University of
California, Berkeley, California
Correspondence
Barry Eichengreen, Department of
Economics, University of California,
530 Evans Hall #3880, Berkeley, CA
97420‐3880.
Email: eichengr@econ.berkeley.edu
Funding information
We thank the Clausen Center at the
University of California, Berkeley for
financial support
Abstract
We consider the correlates of international financial‐center
status. Our estimates point to the flexibility, transparency,
and stability of the economic and social environment as
determinants of financial center‐status. They point also to
roles for monetary and financial stability, financial open-
ness, financial scale and development, technology and size
of government. We draw out the implications of this analysis
for the future prospects of actual and aspiring international
financial centers such as London, New York, and Shanghai.
|
63
EICHENGREEN aNd SHaH
links for completing a high volume of financial transactions and thereby reaping economies of scale
(Lee, Alford, Cresson, & Gardner, 2017). They single out geography as a factor influencing access
to that network (Eichengreen, Lafargette, & Mehl, 2016). They emphasize the information content
of financial assets—whether securities are information sensitive, in which case they are apt to be
traded in multiple centers close to their originators, or information insensitive, in which case trading is
more likely to concentrate in a small handful of venues to leverage thick‐market externalities (Gehrig,
1998). Economic geographers (e.g., Faulconbridge, 2004; Parr & Budd, 2000) incorporate all of these
factors and suggest in addition that individual financial centers constitute part of a larger network
whose collective properties should be taken into account.
The corresponding empirical literature is less than conclusive. Reed (1980), Michie (1991),
Schenk (2002), Lai (2006), and Elliott (2011) present case studies of individual financial centers, but
the generality of their findings remains unclear. Alternatively, Kayral and Karan (2012) and Moosa,
Li, and Jiang (2016) consider survey‐based ratings of competing international financial centers. They
compare different financial centers at a point in time, attempting to identify the determinants of the
attractiveness of those centers as measured by the surveys in question. For the most part, however, they
have obtained few robust results.
This paper extends the comparative approach of this last set of studies. Rather than limiting the
analysis to a single point in time, it assembles an annual panel of financial center ratings spanning a
decade. More data make for more statistical power and more definitive results.
The estimates point to the flexibility, transparency and stability of the economic and social en-
vironment as determinants of financial‐center status. Financial centers are more attractive when the
country in which they are located ranks high on the Heritage Foundation's index of economic freedom.
They are more attractive when the host country rates higher on the World Economic Forum's index of
global competitiveness. They are more attractive when corruption in the host country is less pervasive.
A second set of variables points to the importance of monetary and financial stability. Financial
centers are more attractive when the host‐country government has a higher sovereign rating from com-
mercial credit rating agencies. According to some regressions, they are more attractive when inflation
is low and stable.
A third cluster of variables captures the importance of financial scale and development. Financial
centers are more attractive when located in a country where equity‐market capitalization as a share
of GDP is higher, reflecting the existence of larger and better‐developed financial markets. Relatedly,
financial centers are more likely to be situated in large countries, whose residents are apt to generate a
large volume of financial transactions, indicative of the importance of economies of scale and scope.
Technology also matters. Financial centers are apt to be located where internet usage is higher,
consistent with the emphasis in some pertinent literature on the importance of information, commu-
nications, and data‐processing technology. They are more attractive when situated in countries where
high‐tech products constitute a relatively large share of manufactured exports, consistent with a role
for the technological sophistication of the economy more generally.
Finally, there is at least some indication that financial centers tend to be situated in countries with
larger governments. Government is a source of contract‐enforcement services and property rights
protections valued by investors, and under‐resourced public sectors are less able to provide them. In
addition, relatively open economies have larger governments, as established in previous studies (e.g.,
Alesina & Wacziarg, 1998; Rodrik, 1998). A large public sector can help to buffer the citizenry from
external shocks, with positive implications for the sustainability of openness. Given the value that in-
ternational investors attach to de facto openness, the size of the public sector is thus another plausible
indicator of the attractiveness of a financial center.

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT