Student loans: When is risk sharing desirable?

AuthorItzhak Zilcha,Bernhard Eckwert
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12126
Published date01 June 2017
Date01 June 2017
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12126
Student loans: When is risk sharing desirable?
Bernhard Eckwertand Itzhak Zilcha
In higher education, pure credit market funding leads to underinvestment due to insufficient
risk pooling, while pure income-contingent loan funding leads to overinvestment. We analyze
whether funding diversity – a market structure in whichcredit markets coexist alongside income-
contingent loan funding – might restore efficiency of the educational investment process. In
the absence of government intervention, we find that funding diversity improves pooling of
individual income risks and, under some condition, leads to higher social welfare than pure
credit marketfunding . Ifcombined w ith a policy that restricts accessto higher education, funding
diversity even achieves full investment efficiency and strictly dominates credit marketfunding .
Key wor ds higher education, funding diversity, human capital formation.
JEL classification D31, H31, I22.
Accepted 14 October 2015
1 Introduction
Higher education financing faces two main problems which may lead to underinvestment in skilled
human capital formation. The first problem is due to the peculiarities of human capital which
prevent this form of capital from being used as loan collateral. As a consequence, banks arereluctant
to provide higher education loans (see, for example, Galor and Zeira 1993). The second problem
is caused by imperfections in the market for risk bearing. Investment in higher education is risky
because students are at least partially ignorant about their abilities and, hence, about the returns on
their investments. Yet, financial markets are unlikely to provide adequate pooling or diversification
of these risks due to the existence of moral hazard incentives in an agent’s acquisition of human
capital and in his performance in the labor market.
As a possible response to these market failuresthe creation of income-contingent loan-repayment
programs has been suggested (Friedman 1962; Nerlove 1975; Chapman 2006). Income-contingent
loans have the special characteristic that the terms of repayment depend on the borrowers’ future
incomes: individuals with higher incomes have higher repayment obligations. Such loan contracts
not only allow students to pool (part of) their future income risks but can also be used to transfer
risks on investment in human capital from borrowersand lenders to third parties. Yet, while income-
contingent loans may ease credit constraints and improve risk allocation, they often also imply
significant cross-subsidization between subgroups of students with different future income prospects
which may lead to excessive investment in higher education. In fact, students with poor income
Bielefeld University,Bielefeld, Germany. Email: beckwert@wiwi.uni-bielefeld.de
TelAviv University and College of Management Academic Studies, Israel.
Financial support from the Pinhas Sapir Center for Development, Tel Aviv University, is gratefully acknowledged. We
especially wish to acknowledge receiving helpful suggestions from an anonymous referee.
International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 217–231 © IAET 217
International Journal of Economic Theory
Risk sharing and student loans Bernhard Eckwert and Itzhak Zilcha
prospects are more likely to take out education loans under such a scheme than students with
good income prospects and, hence, the human capital formation process is characterized by adverse
selection (Eckwert and Zilcha 2010, 2012).
Typically, none of these schemes exists in isolation. Our paper therefore concentrates upon the
implications of funding diversity: we study the implications of credit funding and income-contingent
loans funding when these two schemes coexist and compete against each other for higher education
finance. For this purpose, we set up a theoretical framework in which individuals live for two
periods. In the “youth” period, agents obtain education and in the “working” period they generate
incomes based on their human capital and skills. At birth, each individual is randomly endowed with
some innate ability which becomes fully known only in the working period. Following compulsory
schooling in the youth period, each individual receivesa (publicly observed) signal which is correlated
to his/her true innate ability. The decision whether to acquire higher education after compulsory
schooling depends on the financing options available to the agent and on the information conveyed
by the signal.
We consider two financing regimes. Under the first regime, the government guarantees access
to credit markets for all students who attend higher education. Under the second regime, which is
the main focus of our study, income-contingent education finance coexists with competitive credit
markets. We find that pure credit market funding leads to underinvestment in higher education.
By contrast, funding diversity leads to overinvestment due to adverse selection. Nevertheless, un-
der some condition, funding diversity dominates pure credit market funding in terms of social
welfare.
Funding diversity in higher education is plagued by adverse selection in two respects. First,
the cross-subsidization within the income-contingent loans program entices students with negative
expected net returns on their investments to participate in the program. This misallocation of
educational investment raises the financing costs for all participants, because the program is not
subsidized by the government and, hence, must break even in equilibrium. Second, the elevated
financing costs within the program provide incentives for students with good income prospects to
shun the program and turn to the credit market for funding. This effect pushes the financing costs
within the program even higher.
The fact that funding diversity alone does not remedy the misallocation of educational invest-
ment suggests a role for government policy. This policy would restrict access to higher education to
individuals with non-negative expected net returns on their investments, given the signals attained
after compulsory schooling. We find that such policy, if combined with funding diversity in higher
education, is quite appropriate as it restores efficiency of the educational investment process and, at
the same time, mitigates the adverse selection problem within the income-contingentloans program.
Moreover,under a p olicy of restricted access, funding diversity always leads to higher social welfare
compared to pure credit market funding.
Our work is related to the theoretical literature that analyzes imperfections in financing modes
of higher education. One of the earlier contributions is Loury (1981) who analyzes imperfections in
the form of exogenous borrowing constraints for education funding. Since then, a number of papers
have integrated similar constraints into more extended equilibrium models of higher education. For
example, De Gregorio and Kim (2000) and De Fraja (2002) develop models in which students from
better-off households are less affected by borrowing constraints, which leads to an elitist education
provision in equilibrium. Using a Kehoe and Levine (1993) framework, Andolfatto and Gervais
(2006) and de la Croix and Michel (2007) analyze the role of endogenous liquidity constraints for
educational decisions and human capital formation.
218 International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 217–231 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT