Stock Market Responses Under Quantitative Easing: State Dependence and Transparency in Monetary Policy

AuthorYoshiyuki Nakazono,Satoshi Ikeda
Published date01 December 2016
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0106.12158
Date01 December 2016
STOCK MARKET RESPONSES UNDER QUANTITATIVE
EASING: STATE DEPENDENCE AND TRANSPARENCY IN
MONETARY POLICY
YOSHIYUKI NAKAZONO*Yokohama City University
SATOSHI IKEDA State Street Trust and Banking
Abstract. This paper evaluates the effects of unconventional monetary policies adopted by the Bank
of Japan from the year 2001 to 2006. A new measure is proposed to identify a nontraditional mo-
netary policy shock from policy packages under the zero lower bound of short-term nominal interest
rates during the quantitative easing period, using data on intraday 3-month Euroyen futures rates.
We nd that stock markets do not react to a policy surprise in an expected manner and negatively
respond to a monetary easing surprise. Moreover, we nd an asymmetric response during a boom
and a recession and a nonlinear reaction because of increasing uncertainty concerning future ina-
tion dynamics and the enhancement of monetary policy transparency. Our result suggests that it is
difcult to implement unconventional monetary policy to manage agentsexpectations and a lean
against the windpolicy to prevent asset bubbles, particularly at the zero bound.
1. INTRODUCTION
Increasing attention is being paid to the effects of nontraditional monetary
policies of central banks in developed countries. Such policies include asset
purchase programmes and commitment to maintaining easing policies until
ination rates improve. This is because countries rely on monetary policy to un-
derpin economic activities, such as the stabilization policy during deationary
periods in Japan and following the recent nancial turmoil in the United States
and Europe. Now that the central banks in developed countries, such as the
Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank, also adopt nonstandard
monetary policies, including explicit expectation management and large-scale asset
purchase programmes, it is important to investigate the effects of unconventional
monetary policies on economic activities. Many countries now shoulder a substan-
tial debt burden; thus, policy makers have a strong interest in unconventional
monetary policy, which is one of the few macroeconomic policies left remaining.
However, there is no denitive conclusion as to the effects of unconventional mon-
etary policy on macroeconomic variables and nancial markets. It is not easy to exam-
ine the effects of nonstandard monetary policy; a conventional way of identifying a
monetary policy shock is no longer valid under the zero lower bound on short-term
nominal interest rates. For example, the Bank of Japan lowered the overnight call
rates to almost 0% and changed the main operating target for money market opera-
tions from the current uncollateralized overnight call rate to the outstanding balance
of thecur rent accounts in 2001.At the same time, the Bank of Japan gave more de-
tailed description of the commitment to maintaining the easing policy until the
*Address for Correspondence: International College of Arts and Sciences, Yokohama City Univer-
sity, E-mail: nakazono@yokohama-cu.ac.jp
Pacic Economic Review, 21: 5 (2016) pp. 560580
doi: 10.1111/1468-0106.12158
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd
bs_bs_banner
consumer priceindex (nationwide statisticsexclude perishables) reachesstability at
0% or higher on a year-on-year basis,1and announced increases in the outright
purchase of long-term government bonds. While the Bank of Japan adopted the
policy package to stimulate the economy, it is difcult for researchers to capture
a nontraditional monetary policy surprise in a traditional way such as measuring
change in overnight call rates around the policy window.
Based on recent nonstandard monetary policy developments, the present
paper proposes a new measure to identify a shock from quantitative easing by
the Bank of Japan during the period 2001 to 2006 and evaluates the effects on
stock markets using the intraday data on 3-month Euroyen futures.2Instead
of employing a conventional identication process, such as using overnight call
rates or the amount of current account balances that represents the policy target
during the quantitative easing period, we adopt the Euroyen futures rate that un-
derlies the 3-month London Interbank Offered Rate (LIBOR) to measure the
unconventional monetary policy shock from a policy package, including, for in-
stance, a commitment policy, asset purchasing programmes and the accumula-
tion of current account balances.
Several published studies, including Baumeister and Benati (2013), Bernanke
et al. (2004), Florackis et al. (2014), Fujiki and Shiratsuka (2002), Fujiwara
(2006), Inoue and Okimoto (2008), Iwata and Wu (2006), Nakajima (2011),
Nakajima et al. (2011) and Schenkelberg and Watzka (2013) elaborate on the
identication of a monetary policy surprise under the zero lower bound. Based
on a vector autoregression approach, Fujiwara (2006), Inoue and Okimoto
(2008), Nakajima (2011), Nakajima et al. (2011) and Schenkelberg and Watzka
(2013) study the effects of monetary policy at the zero bound. However, the data
used in Fujiki and Shiratsuka (2002), Fujiwara (2006) and Inoue and Okimoto
(2008) are limited before 2003, and Nakajima (2011) assumes that short-term in-
terest rates have a xed lower bound. Although Schenkelberg and Watzka
(2013) cover the quantitative easing period, they do not consider the effects of
a commitment policy for the management of expectations, which is the key con-
cept for conducting monetary policy at the zero bound.3
Using a new measure, we propose that nancial markets do not react to a
policy surprise in the way that economic theory would predict; rather, the nan-
cial markets respond negatively even to monetary easing and contrary to expec-
tations. The evidence that a tightening surprise is positively related to stock
returns is consistent with the literature on the state-dependent reaction in
Kontonikas et al. (2013). Second, we nd a complex reaction by stock markets
to a policy surprise at the zero bound. As unexpected, monetary policy tighte-
ning decreases stock prices, which is consistent with economic theory; stock
prices also decrease, even when an unexpected monetary policy shock is
accommodative. Third, we nd that the nonlinear response vanishes after the
1(Ueda, 2012b) notes that this policy commitment is an explicit version of expectations
management.
2Three-month Euroyen futures are listed on the Tokyo Financial Exchange.
3See (Eggertsson and Woodford, 2003) and (Eggertsson and Woodford, 2004)
STOCK MARKET RESPONSES UNDER QUANTITATIVE EASING 561
© 2016 John Wiley & Sons Australia, Ltd

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT