Specification Error, Estimation Risk, and Conditional Portfolio Rules

AuthorMurray Carlson,David A. Chapman,Hong Yan,Ron Kaniel
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/irfi.12110
Published date01 June 2017
Date01 June 2017
Specification Error, Estimation Risk,
and Conditional Portfolio Rules*
MURRAY CARLSON
,DAVID A. CHAPMAN
,RON KANIEL
§
AND
HONG YAN
Finance Division, Sauder School, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, British
Columbia, Canada,
McIntire School, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA, USA,
§
Simon School of Business, University of Rochester and IDC Herzliya, and CEPR,
Rochester, NY, USA and
Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai,
China
ABSTRACT
In characterizing the data-generating process for excess returns, an investor
faces both parameter uncertainty (or estimation risk) and specication error.
We examine the trade-off between these two effects, in the context of an
optimal consumption/portfolio decision problem, by considering a minimal
extension of the standard assumption of a linear vector autoregression for
excess returns. The key additional assumption in our data-generating process
is a positive linear relationship between market volatility and lagged market
dividend yields. This simple specication is consistent with a long sample of
U.S. data. We show that volatility adjusted rules are substantially less sensitive
to variation in dividend yields, and volatility-related specication error is
economically signicant even when the decisions are based on sample
estimates from data sets of a realistic size.
I. INTRODUCTION
The impact of excess return predictability on optimal consumption and portfolio
choice has received a substantial amount of attention in the recent academic
literature. The emphasis has been on measuring the quantitative signicance of
return predictability for specic utility functions that are common in the
* We would like to thank Brian Balyeat, Ravi Bansal, Alexandre Baptista, Michael Brennan, Yeung
Lewis Chan, John Cochrane, Ron Gallant, Lorenzo Garlappi, Rick Green, John Heaton, Eric Hughson,
Chris Jones, Chris Lamoureux, Jun Liu, Nathalie Moyen, Sheridan Titman, Stathis Tompaidis, Ross
Valkanov, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Cornell, HKUST, Arizona, UCLA,
Colorado, Indiana, North Carolina, Penn State, Texas, Texas A&M, Wisconsin, and the 2002 AFA
meetings for helpful comments on various stages of this research. We would also like to thank Sergey
Kolos for research assistance.
© 2016 International Review of Finance Ltd. 2016
International Review of Finance, 17:2, 2017: pp. 263288
DOI: 10.1111/ir.12110
theoretical asset pricing literature. One nding of the early papers in this area is
that optimal investment policies seem to be very responsive to the level of the
dividend yield (the predictor variable used in these analyses). For example,
Campbell and Viceira (1999, 2000) nd that a constant relative risk aversion in-
vestor with a risk aversion coefcient of four allocates (roughly) 20% of her
wealth to the risky asset when the excess return is zero and 130% of her wealth
to the risky asset when it is 6%. Balduzzi and Lynch (1999) reach similar
conclusions.
1
The studies cited above estimate a particular data-generating process (DGP)
for market excess returns and the market dividend yield, and then they compute
the optimal policy at the point estimates of the parameters of the exogenous
DGP. Kandel and Stambaugh (1996) and Barberis (2000) point out that param-
eter uncertainty, alternatively called estimation risk,can have an important
impact on both the measurement of the economic signicance of return pre-
dictability and on how aggressively an investor will trade on the apparent pre-
dictability found in a given sample of stock returns. In all of the studies
mentioned so far, excess returns evolve as a restricted version of a rst-order vec-
tor autoregression (VAR) of market excess return and dividend yield, driven by
independent normally distributed shocks with constant variance. While this
choice has the virtue of simplicity, the specication of a constant excess return
variance is clearly inconsistent with the large empirical literature that docu-
ments time-varying volatility in stock returns. In addition, the effect of parame-
ter uncertainty on the economic signicance of specication error is an
important open issue.
In this paper, we address two questions: (i) how big is the economic signi-
cance, as measured by utility cost, of ignoring the volatility dynamics in the
DGP when investors make their portfolio allocations based on a mis-specied
model? and (ii) does the estimation risk of parameters mitigate the economic
signicance of specication error? We examine these issues from the perspective
of a correctly specied DGP and assess the utility cost of a CRRA investor who
estimates a mis-specied model based on the data that are generated from the
true model. While our approach is decidedly non-Bayesian, it provides a reason-
able way to assess the economic consequence of a common practice of calibrat-
ing a pre-specied DGP for portfolio choice problems based on return
predictability.
The DGP that we use allows both excess return and dividend yield volatilities
to be linear functions of the lagged market dividend yield. This specication is a
small departure from the standard assumptions, and it has the considerable
advantage of simplicity, because mean and volatility dynamics are driven by a
single (observable) state variable. Furthermore, we demonstrate that these
volatility dynamics are qualitatively consistent with the properties of conditional
1 See Lynch (2001) and Campbell, Chan, and Viceira (2003) for multivariate extensions of these
studies.
International Review of Finance
© 2016 International Review of Finance Ltd. 2016264

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT