Soft power and exports

Published date01 November 2019
AuthorAndrew K. Rose
Date01 November 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12435
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:1573–1590. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie
|
1573
© 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
Received: 30 May 2019
|
Revised: 1 July 2019
|
Accepted: 8 July 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12435
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Soft power and exports
Andrew K.Rose
Haas School of Business,University of
California, Berkeley, CA
Correspondence
Andrew K. Rose, Haas School of Business,
University of California, Berkeley, CA
94720‐1900.
E‐mail: arose@haas.berkeley.edu. http://
faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/arose
Abstract
This paper seeks to help establish a stylized fact: a country’s
exports rise when its leadership is approved by other coun-
tries. I show this using a standard gravity model of bilateral
exports, a panel of data from 2006 through 2017, and an an-
nual Gallup survey that asks people in up to 157 countries
whether they approve of the job performance of the leader-
ship of China, Germany, Russia, the United Kingdom and
the United States. Holding other things constant, a coun-
try’s exports are higher if its leadership is approved by the
importer—“soft power” promotes exports. The soft power
effect is statistically and economically significant; a 1%
increase in leadership approval raises exports by around
two‐thirds of a percent. This effect is reasonably robust, and
different measures of soft power deliver similar results. I con-
servatively estimate that the >20 percentage point decline in
foreign approval of American leadership between 2016 (the
final year of Obama’s presidency) and 2017 (Trump’s first
year) lowered American exports by at least U.S.$3 billion.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F14; F59
1
|
INTRODUCTION AND MOTIVATION
The objective of this paper is modest: it tries to help establish an empirical linkage between the pop-
ularity of a country’s leadership and international trade flows. Using standard techniques, I find that
countries whose leadership is approved abroad tend to sell more exports, holding all else equal. More
generally, I hope to demonstrate that “soft power”—the ability of one country to attract or persuade
citizens in another—is a significant determinant of export demand. Countries that are more favorably
viewed by foreigners tend to sell more.
1574
|
ROSE
2
|
METHODOLOGY AND GRAVITY DATA
I am interested in whether countries are affected in any tangible way by fluctuations in soft power.
In particular, I test whether changes in foreign perceptions of soft power affect export sales, all else
equal. In doing so, I hope to establish a new stylized fact linking trade to soft power.
I use a standard gravity model of international trade to account for other influences on bilateral
exports besides soft power. In particular, I pursue “theory‐consistent estimation” of the gravity equa-
tion, closely following the suggestions in the authoritative survey by Head and Mayer (2014). I focus
on their “LSDV” (least squares with time‐varying country dummy variables) technique that they show
works well in many situations. I estimate:
where ln(Xijt) denotes the natural logarithm of the nominal value of bilateral exports from country i to
country j at time t, measured as the average of FOB exports from i to j and CIF imports into j from i;
SOFTPOWERijt denotes a bilateral measure of the soft power that i is perceived to have in country j
at time t; D is the great‐circle distance between i and j; Lang is a binary variable that is unity if i and
j have a common language and zero otherwise; Cont is unity if i and j share a land border and zero
otherwise; RTA is unity if i and j belong to the same regional trade agreement and zero otherwise;
Colony is unity if i colonized j or vice versa and zero otherwise; β is a vector of nuisance coefficients;
{λit} is a complete set of time‐varying exporter binary variable fixed effects; {ψjt} is a complete set of
time‐varying importer binary variable fixed effects; and εij represents the myriad other influences on
exports, assumed to be well behaved.
The coefficient of interest is γ, the effect (on bilateral exports) of the exporter’s soft power over the
importer, ceteris paribus. I estimate this equation with least squares, using standard errors robust to
clustering by dyadic (ij) pair.
In practice, most of the variation in exports is explained by the “monadic” country–time fixed ef-
fects (one set each for the exporter and importer), which control a host of other influences on bilateral
exports. For instance, any general short‐term effect on American sales arising from the 2017 ascen-
dance of President Trump is accounted for by the 2017 American exporter fixed effect. Similarly,
any effect on Egyptian imports arising from the 2011 Arab Spring is taken out by the 2011 Egyptian
importer fixed effect. Anything that is specific and common to a country and a year—such as the size
of its economy, population, culture, policy uncertainty, leadership, or military spending, for either the
exporter or the importer—is accounted for by the fixed effects. Any effect of bilateral soft power on
exports is estimated conditional on—and above and beyond—both these fixed effects, and the other
determinants in Equation 1. This is a demanding requirement.
2.1
|
Gravity data
I rely on annual trade data drawn from the Direction of Trade data set assembled by the International
Monetary Fund. The data set covers bilateral trade between over 200 IMF country codes between
1948 and 2017.1
Bilateral trade on FOB exports and CIF imports is recorded in U.S. dollars. To this,
I add a number of dyadic variables necessary to estimate the gravity model, including distance, the
presence of a common land border and language, colonial history, and date of independence (these
are taken from the CIA’s World Factbook). I obtain data from the World Trade Organization to create
(1)
ln (
Xijt
)
=gSOFTPOWERijt +𝛽1ln
(
Dij
)
+𝛽2Langij +𝛽3Contij +𝛽4RTA
ijt
+𝛽
5
Colony
ij
+
{
𝜆
it}
+
{
𝜓
jt}
+𝜀
ijt

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT