Social norms and cooperation

Date01 December 2018
AuthorBryan C. McCannon
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12160
Published date01 December 2018
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12160
Social norms and cooperation
Bryan C. McCannon
A theoretical framework is introduced to model social norms using the tools of psychological
game theory. In the prisoner’s dilemma game, a preference for norm compliance can lead to
cooperation arising with a positive probability,and if this preference is sufficiently strong, occur-
ring as a pure strategy equilibrium. Thus, cooperation can arise as a social norm in a one-shot
prisoner’s dilemma game without repeated play,communication, or sanctions.
Key wor ds cooperation, norm compliance, prisoner’s dilemma, psychological game theory,
social norm
JEL classification D84, D03, C72
Accepted 2 June2017
1 Introduction
An emerging literature in experimental economics has developed, highlighting the role of social
norms in strategic decision-making. As formalized by Bicchieri (2006), a social norm arises when
(a) players have beliefs about what the other player(s)w ill do and (b) contingentlycomply w ith that
norm, that is, they gain from norm compliance (or rather,lose from violating the norm). Exper imen-
tal evidence has shown that social norms explain behavior well in a number of environments such
as altruistic giving in the dictator game (Bicchieri and Xiao 2009; Erkut et al. 2015), punishment in
the public goods game (Carpenter and Matthews 2009), reciprocity in the trust game (Bicchieri et al.
2011), extraction in a common resource game (DeAngelo et al. 2017), and profitable punishment
(Xiao 2013), to name a few.
While the experimental results are well documented, a theoretical framework has not been
developed. In this note I apply the tools of psychological game theory (Geanakoplos et al. 1989)to
provide a model of social norm compliance. Traditional game-theoretic models presume that utility
depends on actions. Psychologicalgame theor y extendsthe field by considering scenarios where utility
depends on beliefs about both actions and beliefs (Dufwenberg 2006). A player with psychological
preferencesgains from the direct payoff from the game, but also, for example, his assessment regarding
others’ beliefs about his choices. By having utility defined on actions, rather than solely on outcomes,
motivations not previously appreciated can be studied.
There are some examples of applying psychological game theory. Charness and Dufwenberg
(2006) use the framework to explain the making of promises in an experiment. Dufwenberg et al.
(2011) use it to model guilt aversion and provide evidence in experiments of public goods games.
McCannon (2015) uses a framework of psychological games to explain leadership and differing
levels of contributions in sequential- versus simultaneous-move public goods games. Theoretical
Department of Economics, West Virginia University, Morgantown, West Virginia, USA. Email: bryan.c.mccannon@
gmail.com
International Journal of Economic Theory 14 (2018) 303–307 © IAET 303
International Journal of Economic Theory

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT