Social comparisons in consumption, international capital flows and tax competition

AuthorJuin‐Jen Chang,Yi‐Ling Cheng,Shin‐Kun Peng
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/ijet.12117
Date01 March 2017
Published date01 March 2017
doi: 10.1111/ijet.12117
Social comparisons in consumption, international capital
flows and tax competition
Juin-Jen Chang,Yi-Ling Chengand Shin-Kun Peng
This paper explores the implications of consumption externalities for capital mobility,the distri-
bution of firms and tax competition. In the absence of tax competition, the country with higher
consumption externality attracts more capital/firms. In contrast, under tax competition, because
the country with higher consumption externality will impose a higher tax rate on capital, due
to the strong negative effect of taxation, the country with lower externality attracts more capital.
Besides, as trade openness increases, capital agglomerates in the country with lower consumption
externality. We also show that there may exist an efficiency-enhancing role for tax competition.
Key wor ds consumption externality, footloose capital, trade liberalization, tax competition
JEL classification E21, F12, F15, H87
Accepted 27 May2016
1 Introduction
The desire for social status is one of the most important factors driving human behavior. People
can display their social status to others by conspicuous consumption. Such conspicuous behaviors
increase interpersonal influence, giving rise to negative externalities for others. To shed light on social
comparisons in consumption, economists characterize “keeping up with the Joneses” (KUJ) prefer-
ences, indicating that an individual consumer derives her utility by comparing her own consumption
with a reference level which is typically defined as the economy’s averagele velof consumption. With
the comparison of preferences, not only has the importance of consumption externalities been re-
peatedly emphasized, but their implications have also been widely examined in manycontexts. In the
literature, consumption externalities have provided a possible explanation for the equity premium
puzzle (Abel 1990; Gal´
ı 1994; Campbell and Cochrane 1999), and explorations have been carried
out of the patterns of growth (Carroll et al. 1997, 2000; Alonso-Carrera et al. 2004; Turnovsky and
Monteiro 2007), the properties of the business cycle (Lettau and Uhlig 2000), and the effects of
Academia Sinica, Nankang, Taipei, Taiwan.
TunghaiUniversity, Taichung,Taiwan.
Academia Sinica, Nankang, Taipei, Taiwan.Email: speng@econ.sinica.edu.tw
Wethank the editor and an anonymous referee for their constructive comments, which helped us to improve the paper.
Also, we are grateful for valuable comments and suggestions fromWen-Tai Hsu, Tomoya Mori, Ping Wang,and Dao-Zhi
Zeng, as well as participants of the Fifth Asian Seminar in Regional Science, the 2015 annual meeting of the Taiwan
Economic Association, and the CEANA session in the 2016 AEA annual meeting. Financial support from the Ministry of
Science and Technology(MOST 104-2410-H-029-004) is gratefully acknowledged.
International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 47–71 © IAET 47
International Journal of Economic Theory
Social comparisons in consumption Juin-Jen Chang et al.
optimal tax policies (Ljungqvist and Uhlig 2000; Chang et al. 2012), together with their inefficient
consequences (Dupor and Liu 2003; Alonso-Carrera et al. 2004, 2005).
In spite of their importance, consumption externalities seem to be neglected in the literature on
international trade and economic geography.The aforementioned studies confine their attention to a
closed economy,leaving international tr ade and the spatial distribution of capital/firms unexplored.
Recently,Valente (2009) built a two-country endogenous growth model where the utility of agents in
developing countries is affected by consumption gaps with advanced economies, and documented
that international status-seeking behaviors (or between-country social comparisons) tend to reverse
growth differentials in favor of the developing country.While his model endogenizes trade balances,
the international mobility of capital (spatial location of firms) is still ruled out. Going beyond the
existing studies, this paper attempts to explore how social comparisons in consumption affect not
only international trade, but also the geographical concentration of economic activities and the
optimal tax rate for the internationally mobile capital in the process of economic integration.1To
the best of our knowledge, this is the first work that explores such an important issue not only for
its theoretical insights, but also for its wide-ranging policy implications in a framework of the new
trade theory (NTT).
Ever since Krugman (1980), trade integration and factor mobility have been important features
in determining the distribution of firms as well as welfare in the framework of the NTT and the
new economic geography (NEG). The footloose-capital (FC) model of Martin and Rogers (1995)
is widely applied in the NTT literature to examine various issues related to international capital
mobility, industry location, country size and tax competition (e.g., Kind et al. 2000; Baldwin et al.
2003; Ottaviano and Ypersele 2005; Peralta and Ypersele 2005; Chen and Zeng 2014). Going beyond
the existing literature, this paper providesnew insig ht byincorpor ating agents’status-seeking motives
in consumption externalities into an otherwise standard FC model in an NTT framework, in which
international trade incurs iceberg transport costs, capital is fully mobile between the two countries,
and both countries engage in tax competition in order to attract internationally mobile capital.
Our main findings are summarized as follows. In our analytical study, and in the absence of tax
competition, we show that the equilibrium amount/number of capital/firms in a country increases
with the extent of the consumption externalities in this country, but decreasesw ith that extentin the
rival country. In contrast tothe findings of Martin and Rogers (1995), the equilibrium dist ribution of
capital/firms ambiguously responds to trade integration, and is dependent on the relative magnitude
of consumption externalities (the consumption externality effect) between the two countries.
With regard to the tax competition between the two countries, in order to achieve the social
optimum, our numerical study shows that the government could tax rather than subsidize capital
under a Nash equilibrium. In general, a country is more likely to levy a capital income tax when it has
relatively intensive social comparisons in consumption,or when there exist more trade barr iers (i.e.,
low trade openness). This result stands in sharp contrast to the conventional resultof the “race to the
bottom,”as proposed by Baldwin et al. (2003), Ottaviano and Ypersele (2005), and Peng et al. (2016).
The question of whether internationally mobile capital should be taxed is an important issue and is
comprehensively examinedin the NT T literature. The conventionalwisdom indicates that capital tax
competition leads to a race to the bottom, in the sense that the desire to attract internationally mobile
capital, together with trade integration, results in inefficiently low tax rates on capital incomes (see,
1Our paper differs from Valente (2009) in twosig nificant respects.First, we specify w ithin-country social comparisons,
rather than between-country ones, which allows us to provide new implications for the countries with various degrees of
social comparison with the international trade literature. Second, his study focuses on long-run economic growth, while
our attention is directed toward international tax competitionand the spatial distr ibution of firms.
48 International Journal of Economic Theory 13 (2017) 47–71 © IAET

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT