Protection and skills: Does trade policy favor low‐skill workers?

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12406
AuthorScott Bradford
Published date01 August 2019
Date01 August 2019
Rev Int Econ. 2019;27:981–1000. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/roie © 2019 John Wiley & Sons Ltd
|
981
1
|
INTRODUCTION
Many people believe that international trade unduly benefits the rich and that trade barriers provide
extra help for less‐skilled workers. Also, the empirical endogenous protection literature strongly im-
plies that protection decreases with skill levels. This paper presents evidence against this conventional
wisdom.
Regressions based on an explicit political economy model with search frictions and endogenous
unemployment imply that protection and average skill levels in U.S. industries have a mound‐shaped
relationship. The analysis indicates that, for the set of sectors whose average skill level is below a
certain cut‐off, protection increases with average skills, because, for these sectors, the hiring response
from a given price hike increases with that sector's skill level. This greater hiring response results from
the fact that jobs with higher skills give more value to those workers, making them more inclined to
accept an offer. The greater hiring response to a price increase, in turn, creates more political support
Received: 1 April 2018
|
Revised: 7 February 2019
|
Accepted: 12 April 2019
DOI: 10.1111/roie.12406
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
Protection and skills: Does trade policy favor low‐
skill workers?
ScottBradford
Economics Department,Brigham Young
University, Provo, Utah
Correspondence
Scott Bradford, Economics Department,
Brigham Young University, Provo, UT
84602.
Email: bradford@byu.edu
Abstract
Many believe that international trade barriers in rich nations
help low‐skill workers. Also, the empirical endogenous pro-
tection literature strongly implies that protection decreases
with skill levels. This paper presents evidence against this
conventional wisdom. Regressions based on a political
economy model with search frictions and unemployment
imply that protection and skill levels actually have a mound‐
shaped relationship: industries with skills in the middle
range get more protection than industries at either end of the
distribution. Apparently, the politics of trade policy trump
social concerns, rendering protection less “progressive”
than is commonly believed.
JEL CLASSIFICATION
F13; D72; D78
982
|
BRADFORD
for policy makers. Thus, they grant more protection to higher‐skilled industries, not less. It appears
that the politics surrounding trade policy can trump social concerns, rendering the structure of pro-
tection less “progressive” than many would like to believe. The recent tariffs imposed by the Trump
Administration against steel, aluminum, and Chinese goods provide anecdotal evidence in favor of this
conclusion, since those tariffs seem to favor workers with skills in the middle range, as opposed to the
lowest‐skilled workers. In constrast, I do find that the conventional wisdom holds for sectors above a
certain skill cut‐off: For these sectors, higher skill levels lead to less protection.
Many empirical studies have analyzed the skill–protection connection. Ray (1981), Marvel and
Ray (1983), Baldwin (1985), Trefler (1993), Gawande (1998), and Gawande and Bandyopadhyay
(2000) all find a negative correlation between skill levels and protection across U.S. industries. I know
of none that finds a significantly positive correlation. These regression analyses are enlightening,
but they are not derived from explicit models and thus have a higher chance of suffering from spec-
ification error than do analyses based on explicit modeling.1
Esfahani (2005) formally incorporates
skills into a protection model. In his model, sectors with lower skill levels face more vulnerability
to negative shocks, owing to incomplete insurance markets, and thus gain more from protection. He
finds, in accordance with the other literature, that having more workers whose skills are below that of
the highest group leads to higher protection. His paper, though, like all others known to me, considers
only a linear protection–skills relation.2
In this paper, I extend the previous literature by examining the possibility of a nonlinear rela-
tion between protection and skills within an estimating framework derived from an explicit protec-
tion model. The model follows Bradford (2006) and includes four groups: the government chooses
protection levels to maximize votes, producers maximize rents through lobbying, and workers and
consumers vote according to protection's effect on their economic welfare. Thus, this model has two
channels of government influence: lobbying and voting.3
Search‐generated unemployment affects vot-
ing. Politicians can win voting support, in addition to lobbying support, by imposing protection and
reducing unemployment. The model extends Bradford (2006) by incorporating skills: in the search
framework that describes the labor market, a price increase's effect on unemployment depends on
workers' average skill level.
Another concern with previous studies is how protection is measured. Older studies have used tar-
iff rates while more recent ones have generally used nontariff barrier (NTB) indices. Tariff rates alone
are inadequate, and NTB indices have troubling flaws. This study uses newer measures of protection
that I believe are more reliable.
2
|
THE MODEL
2.1
|
The economy
As with much of the rest of the literature, I assume that there are
n+1
goods and that all consumers
have identical quasilinear tastes given by
u
=z
0
+
n
i=1
u
i
(z
i)
, where
z
denotes the quantity consumed
of each good. Each
ui
is differentiable and strictly concave, and
z0
is a background numeraire good.
Each person has enough income to consume all goods. The quasilinear tastes imply that demand for
each good depends only on its price. I normalize the population to one. Thus, total consumer surplus
for each good is
cs(pi)=ui[di(pi)]pidi(pi)
, where pi is the price, and
di(pi)
is demand.
For production, I modify the model in Bradford (2006), which, like Davidson, Martin and Matusz
(1999) (DMM), adapts the continuous time search model of Mortensen and Pissarides (1999) (MP)
to an international trade setting. Production results from workers matching with firms, and those
matches break up from time to time, requiring labor and capital to search again. In this paper, I plow

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT