Pricing the ECB's forward guidance with the EONIA swap curve

AuthorMatthieu Picault
Published date01 April 2017
Date01 April 2017
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1002/ijfe.1572
Received: 29 July 2015 Revised: 4 July 2016 Accepted: 23 November 2016
DOI 10.1002/ijfe.1572
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Pricing the ECB’s forward guidance with the EONIA swap curve
Matthieu Picault1,2
1IESEG School of Management, 3 rue de la Digue
Lille, 59000, France
2Aix-Marseille University, France
Correspondence
Matthieu Picault, IESEG School of Management, 3
rue de la Digue, Lille 59000, France.
Email: m.picault@ieseg.fr
JEL Classification: E52; E58; G14
Abstract
On July 4, 2013, following several other major central banks, the European Central
Bank (ECB) gave forthe first time forward guidance on interest rates, which affected
market participants’ expectations of future interest rates in the context of a Zero
Lower Bound. Using an ARMAX(1,1) model in which the effect of the commu-
nication of negative macroeconomic news was disentangled from the commitment
positive shock, the impact of the forward guidance on money market interest rates
is estimated through the Euro Overnight Index Average swap, also called overnight
index swap, at maturities between 2 months and 10 years using abnormal returns
from an event study. The results and robustness checks suggest that the ECB’s guid-
ance lowered overnight index swaprates for maturities within 10 mont hs to 3 years.
These results imply the existence of a commitment effect from the ECB’scommuni-
cation. In the context of decreasing market liquidity because of the 3-year long-term
refinancing operation repayment, market participants priced the low period of
interest rates until mid-2016.
KEYWORDS
ECB, event study, forward Guidance, LTRO, monetary Policy, OIS
1INTRODUCTION
Already used by several central banks (New Zealand since
1997, Norway since 2005, Sweden since 2007, and the Czech
Republic since 2008)1as a standard monetary policy tool, the
forward guidance from the European Central Bank (ECB) and
other major central banks, such as the Federal Reserve, the
Bank of Japan, and the Bank of England, appears in the con-
text of a Zero Lower Bound (ZLB) of nominal interest rates.
On July 4, 2013, the ECB gave for the first time in its exis-
tence forward guidance during a press conference by stating
that “The Governing Council expects the key ECB interest
rates to remain at present or lower levels for an extended
time.” This communication was used after the implemen-
tation of balance sheet policies with both quantitative (the
Covered Bond Purchase Programme, the Securities Markets
Programme, and the fixed-rate full allotment for the main
refinancing operations) and qualitative easing (a change in
the maturities of long-term refinancing operation (LTRO)
programs)2.
The forward guidance relative to the interest rate is a com-
munication by the central bank using an explicit statement
about the outlook for future policy rates (Woodford, 2012). By
influencing expected short-term rates, the central bank could
affect in the same direction long-term yields. As the central
bank committed to a future path of policy rates for an impre-
cise or specific time, market participants would adjust their
anticipations of future short-term interest rates. Following the
expectations hypothesis of the interest rate term structure, the
central bank could then influence longer-term yields. This
type of guidance is called “Odyssean” by Campbell, Evans,
Fisher, and Justiniano (2012) as it ties the central bank to
a given future behavior. A commitment implies that regard-
less of macroeconomic developments, the central bank will
maintain the interest rate at a given level (close to the Zero
Lower Bound). However, a commitment might also imply
considering the central bank loss function (see Svensson
(1997) for a quadratic form), a short-term loss for the central
bank as inflation and the output gap deviate from their tar-
gets, while monetary instruments (main policy rates) remain
unchanged. Hence, the central bank will cloud its long-term
objectives as the economic variables deviate from the cen-
tral bank’s objectives. When implemented, the forward guid-
ance is then subject to time-inconsistent decision making
Int J Fin Econ. 2017;22:129–138. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/ijfe Copyright © 2017 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 129

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT