Pricing strategies for dual‐channel supply chains under a trade credit policy

AuthorLiguo Ren,Haodong Chang,Ziping Wang,Juanjuan Qin,Liangjie Xia
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/itor.12634
Date01 September 2020
Published date01 September 2020
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 27 (2020) 2469–2508
DOI: 10.1111/itor.12634
INTERNATIONAL
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
RESEARCH
Pricing strategies for dual-channel supply chains under a trade
credit policy
Juanjuan Qina, Liguo Rena, Liangjie Xiaa,, Ziping Wangband Haodong Changc
aSchool of Business, Tianjin University of Finance and Economics, Tianjin 300222, China
bSchool of Business and Management, MorganState University, Baltimore, MD 21251, USA
cCollege of Business, Purdue UniversityNorthwest, Hammond, IN 46323, USA
E-mail: qjj@tjufe.edu.cn [Qin]; 1281476575@qq.com [Ren]; xialiangjie@tjufe.edu.cn [Xia];
ziping.wang@morgan.edu [Wang]; chang322@pne.edu [Chang]
Received 17 May2018; received in revised form 21 November 2018; accepted 21 January 2019
Abstract
This paper discusses the impact of a trade credit policy on alleviating conflicts arising on a dual-channel
supply chain that includes one manufacturer and one value-added retailer. We use the Stackelberg game
to model the problem and characterize optimal pricing strategies for each supply chain partner, examining
different circumstances in terms of retail price and trade credit contracts. When a consistent price strategy
is applied in the dual channels under conditions of an exogenous credit period, trade credit can help both
partners to achieve win-win situations in the following circumstances: (1) when the retail channel’s market
share is small and the retailer’s interest rate is high; or (2) when the retail channel’s market share is large and
the retailer’sinterest rate is lower than the manufacturer’s. The study also concludes thatwhen an inconsistent
price strategy is applied, a trade credit contract can alleviate channel conflicts when the retailer’s interest
rate is higher than the manufacturer’s. Otherwise, the partners may terminate cooperation. However, when
the manufacturer has the power to determine and set the credit period, trade credit cannot alleviate channel
conflicts under consistent price and inconsistent price scenarios.
Keywords:pricing; supply chain management; practice of operations research (OR); gaming
1. Introduction
More and more firms, such as Nike, Apple, and Samsung, are opening direct channels for selling
products to end customers. These new channels are in addition to the traditional retail channels
(Tsay and Agrawal, 2004). The surge of information technology is playing an important role in
the development of the direct channel business model. The direct channel is different from the
retail channel in a number of ways. The direct channel helps the manufacturer reduce costs, better
understands their customers, and increases revenue. In the retail channel, the retailer works as a
Corresponding author.
C
2019 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2019 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA02148,
USA.
2470 J. Qin et al. / Intl. Trans. in Op. Res.27 (2020) 2469–2508
middleman to gather market demand information and provide some customer support. For the
reasons above, many firms, including Nike, Apple, and Samsung, prefer to use a dual-channel
strategy (Cao et al., 2013). However, the disadvantage of this strategy is that the manufacturer is
now in direct competition with its channel partners. Thus, channel conflict is the main deterrent to
a manufacturer’s decision to adopt a dual-channel model (Mukhopadhyay et al., 2008). Channel
conflict can be reduced through channel coordination, yielding moreprofit for the channel partners
(Cachon, 2003; Cai, 2010). Thus, if a contract can improve the partners’ profits in a dual-channel
supply chain, we define this contract as being able to alleviate channel conflicts.
A trade credit policy is widely used in a dual-channel supply chain, to alleviate channel conflicts
in specific scenarios. A trade credit is a credit that a seller extends to its buyers, allowing delayed
payment for the purchased products (Petersen and Rajan, 1997). Trade credits usually generate
interest revenuefor the buyer, while the seller bears interest costs. Forexample, many manufacturers
of electronic products, such as Samsung and Huawei, sell their products through dual-channel
supply chains. The manufacturers offer a delayed payment policy to the retailers in their retail
channels, to alleviate the channel conflicts. This type of delay creates a capital pool, providing the
retailer significant gains. The gains from this capital pool can be viewed as the incentive for the
retailer’s investment behavior. For example, for each day the payment term is extended, Jd.com
receives more than 160 million yuan in cash flow.1
However, in other scenarios, a trade credit policy may cause manufacturers and retailers to
terminate cooperation in the dual-channel supply chain. Dual channels are associated with long
credit payment terms. As such, some manufacturers suffer cash-flow risks and must terminate
cooperation with the retailers,relying only on their direct channels (Zhao et al., 2015). For example,
some apparel suppliers, such as Jason Wood and Ochirly, have stopped cooperating with Jd.com,
to avoid losses arising from the long credit terms for the delayed payment.2
Thus, a trade creditsignificantly impacts the decisions and levels of cooperation on a dual-channel
supply chain. This study addresses the following research questions: (1) How does a trade credit
affect the pricing strategies of a dual-channel supply chain? (2) Do firms in a dual-channel supply
chain benefit from trade credits? (3) How do the interest rates, market share, and cross price elasticity
affect the decisions and profits made by those in the dual-channel supply chain?
To answer these questions, we first develop an analytical framework to model the dual-channel
supply chain with a trade credit contract. We assume the manufacturer grants a fixed credit term
to the retailer. More specifically, manufacturers usually offer a credit period of 30 days to the home
appliance retailer Gome, and 60 days to the electronic business retailer Jd.com.3We then derive the
optimal decisions of the partners in the supply chain under the trade credit contract considering the
consistent price and inconsistent price strategies. Second, we characterize the optimal solutions in
the supply chain without a trade credit. Third, we compare the solutions in the dual-channel supply
chain with and without the trade credit. Finally, we extend the model, by considering that credit
terms are decided by the manufacturer under consistent price and inconsistent price scenarios in
the dual-channel supply chain.
1http://net.chinabyte.com/199/12681199.shtml(accessed July 25, 2018).
2http://mt.sohu.com/20160623/n455862334.shtml (accessed July 25, 2018).
3http://tech.163.com/api/15/0611/10/ARQSS2U6000915BF.html (accessed July25, 2018).
C
2019 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2019 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
J. Qin et al. / Intl. Trans. in Op. Res.27 (2020) 2469–2508 2471
Our work contributes to existing literature in three main ways. First, this is the first study to
theoretically study the impact of the trade credit contract on the dual-channel supply chain, and
it generates several interesting results and insights. Second, this work addresses pricing strategies
under the trade credit contract, complementing existing literature by focusing on inventory policies
under the trade credit contract. Third, our model reveals whether trade credit can improve partner
profitability in a dual-channel supply chain, and explores the impact of partner interest rates, retail
channel market share, and cross-price elasticity. This approach contrasts with the scenario of a
single-channel supply chain, in which past studies have generally concluded that the trade credit
benefits the partners (e.g., Luo and Zhang, 2012; Gao et al., 2014).
The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the literature review. Section 3
presents the model setup. Section 4 discusses the supply-chain model with/without a trade credit
contract under a consistent pricing strategy. Section 5 analysesthe supply-chain model with/without
a trade credit under an inconsistent pricing strategy. Section 6 extends the models by considering
endogenous credit period decisions. In Section 7, we present our conclusions and managerial
implications.
2. Literat ure review
This section presents a literature review to analyze the dual-channel supply chain and trade credit
contract.
2.1. Dual-channel supply chain
In this section, we mainly focus on the pricing strategiesand channel coordination in a dual-channel
supply chain.
In their research of pricing strategies in a dual-channel supply chain, Yao and Liu (2005) analyze
the pricing strategies using Bertrand and Stackelberg game structures in a dual-channel supply
chain. Dumrongsiri et al. (2008) study a dual channel’s price and service quantity decisions. The
manufacturer decides the direct channel prices, and the retailer decides both the price and order
quantity. Dan et al. (2012) examine the optimal retail services and price decisions in a centralized
and a decentralized dual-channel supply chain, using the two-stage optimization technique and
Stackelberg game. Huang et al. (2012) analyze the pricing and production decisions in dual-channel
supply chains with demand disruptions. Chen (2015) evaluates the influence of price schemes and
cooperative advertising mechanisms on dual-channel supply chain competition. Panda et al. (2015)
discuss pricing and replenishment policies in a dual-channel supply chain under conditions of
continuous unit cost decreases. Cattani et al. (2006) and Li et al. (2016) discuss the consistent
pricing policies of a dual-channel supply chain. Liu et al. (2016) analyze the pricing policies of a
dual-channel supply chain with asymmetric risk aversion information. Zhao et al. (2017) analyze
pricing strategies for complementary products in the dual-channel supply chain.
Researching the coordination of a dual-channel supply chain, Cai et al. (2009) discuss how a
price discount contract can improve a dual-channel supply chain’s performance. Chen et al. (2012)
analyze how a two-part tariff and a profit-sharing agreement can be used to coordinate a dual-
channel supply chain and enable both the manufacturer and retailer to have a win-win. Cao (2014)
C
2019 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2019 International Federation of OperationalResearch Societies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT