Potential additional profits of selling a perishable product due to implementing price discrimination versus implementation costs

AuthorAvi Herbon
Published date01 July 2019
Date01 July 2019
DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/itor.12426
Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 1402–1421
DOI: 10.1111/itor.12426
INTERNATIONAL
TRANSACTIONS
IN OPERATIONAL
RESEARCH
Potential additional profits of selling a perishable product due
to implementing price discrimination versus implementation
costs
Avi Herbon
Department of Management, Bar-Ilan University, Ramat-Gan, Israel
E-mail: avher@bezeqint.net [Herbon]
Received 27 November2016; received in revised form 20 April 2017; accepted 24 April 2017
Abstract
Firms that seek to undertake the course of price discrimination may face obstacles. Answering the question
as to whether the implementation of price discrimination for perishables is beneficial from the perspective
of the seller depends on the total costs of acquiring both consumption information and the technology. We
analyze two models. The first model assumes that sufficient consumer information (e.g., purchasing history)
and the technology for applyingprice discrimination are availableto the decision maker (i.e., the retailer). The
second represents the common situation where the price is identical to all, that is, price discrimination is not
carried out. The optimal prices are derived. Our modeling indicates that even under deterministic demand
mode, lost sales or surplus can be observed due to the absence of consumer information about sensitivity to
a product’s remaining time until expiration. Simulations for evaluating the effect of random demand noise
on the relative profits obtained byboth models surprisingly show that the gap between them decreases under
demand noise. Numerical illustration indicates that the subjective prediction made by the retailer, who has
no accurate consumer information about demand sensitivity, has a significant impact both on the proportion
of the consumer population that benefits from possible price discrimination and on the retailer’s expected
profits.
Keywords:optimization; retailing; price discrimination; consumer information; perishable inventory
1. Introduction
Enormous amounts of wasted inventories, such as unsold fresh produce, as well as increasing
competition are lowering the levels of marginal profits gained by retailers selling perishables. In
the food industry, for example, weight loss, microbial rots, diseases, and insect damage are possible
accelerators of food loss (Hertog et al., 2014). As a result, these retailers are motivated to research
and carry out atypical pricing strategies. One of the suggested pricing strategies for minimizing
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation ofOperational Research Societies
Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA02148,
USA.
A. Herbon / Intl. Trans. in Op. Res. 26 (2019) 1402–1421 1403
these drawbacks is price discrimination. According to this approach, each consumer (or group of
consumers) is assigned a different price. Accordingto the Forrester report, out of 30 online retailers
interviewed in 2000, 57% had plans to try some form of personalized pricing (Johnson et al.,
2000). Radhakrishnan et al.’s (2008) study finds empirical support for the differential business value
created by IT along a numberof process-oriented dimensions. Other examples of utilizing consumer
information are credit-reporting companies that provide businesses with monetary information
about a consumer’s past behavior, or motor insurance companies thatexamine a consumer’s driving
record prior to determining their price. These findings set an optimistic tone forIT as a major causal
driver of differentiation.According to Aydin and Ziya(2009), many sellers have the abilityto identify
individual customers, collect information about them, and track their purchasing behavior (e.g.,
catalog retailers, online retailers, and stores that issue loyalty cards to their customers). Possessing
and analyzing such information may act as a basis for determining more customized pricing.
Fay and Xie (2008) who suggest a selling strategy termed probabilistic selling (PS) find that
probabilistic goods have the fundamental advantage of allowing the seller to benefit from a special
type of buyer heterogeneity. Such a strategy takes advantage of selling probabilistic products (or
opaque selling) to consumers with weak preferences,that is, applying a form of price discrimination.
Different from Fay and Xie (2008) who assume consumers are homogeneous in their evaluations
of the probabilistic product, Huang and Yu (2014) model opaque selling under different levels
of consumer rationality. Compared to online retailers who have a wealth of information about
registered customers, retailers selling perishables (e.g., food and drugs) might face bigger challenges
in the implementation of price discrimination, that is, offering each customer her/his own price.
The expected additional profit and expected cost associated with the implementation of price
discrimination are keyfactors in the decision-making process about whether to apply such a strategy.
Examples of characteristics that affect a customer’s purchasing decision are price, taste, location,
texture, product color and appearance, brand, and shelf life. Although expiration date is openly
presented to consumers (i.e., the duration of time until the expiration date can be easily computed),
different consumers are likely to assign different qualities to the same product and, accordingly,
are likely to have different willingness to pay depending on their personal perspective and their
required duration of utilization of the item (e.g., two days remaining until expiration may be more
than enough for one consumer but unsatisfactory for another). The perceived quality (see Zeithaml,
1988) strongly depends on the prior knowledge of a given individual about the product, as well
as on that individual’s subjective impression of the deterioration in product quality over time. The
remaining shelf life is the only “objective” information regarding the quality of a given product
relative to a fresh one that is available to consumers; therefore, it makes sense that shelf life is
the origin of the heterogeneity of consumers regarding their estimation of a product’s quality. In
order to exemplify consumer information associated with perishables, we consider in this paper
consumer sensitivity to remaining time until expiration of a perishable product. According to
Liu and Serfes (2004), several sources are available to firms in collecting information about the
heterogeneity of their consumers: past transactions, telemarketing or mail surveys, and credit cards
reports. In this research,we address a special case of the general, open question concerning whether
service providers and retailers who implement price discrimination can benefit economically from
heterogeneity in customer willingness to pay for the same product.
This paper draws from the extensive literature on perishable inventory. The literature that focuses
on the price and inventory control of perishables appears in the reviews of Gallego and Van Ryzin
C
2017 The Authors.
International Transactionsin Operational Research C
2017 International Federation of OperationalResearch Societies

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT