Politics of Association of Southeast Asian Nations Economic Cooperation

DOIhttp://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-3131.2011.01175.x
Date01 June 2011
Published date01 June 2011
AuthorRodolfo C. SEVERINO
Politics of Association of Southeast Asian
Nations Economic Cooperation
Rodolfo C. SEVERINO†
Institute of Southeast Asian Studies
This paper discusses the political motivations behind the evolution of economic cooperation in the
Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) from its founding to the measuresag reedupon to
integrate its economy. Those measuresinclude the reduction and elimination of tariffs on and the
removal of nontariff barriers to intra-ASEAN trade, customs reform, the harmonization of product
standards, the liberalization of trade in services, and the strengthening of transportation links. The
paper analyzes the failure to fully carry out those commitments, ascribing it partly to domestic
political obstacles. Finally, it discusses the efficacy of the ASEAN Charter in this regard and the
prospects of achieving an ASEAN Community by 2015.
Key words: ASEAN charter, ASEAN community, integration, obstacle
JEL codes: F1, F4, F5
1. Introduction
The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) Declaration that the founders of the
ASEAN issued in Bangkok on August 8, 1967 laid down seven“aims and purposes” of the
new association. Of these, four had to do with economic,social, and cultural development.
On the basis of subsequent statements and actions, however, one can say that the asso-
ciation’s real purpose was political in nature – to keep the Southeast Asian countries’
many disputes from turning into violent conflict and to keep the region as much as
possible out of the conflicts of major powers. In his book, Southeast Asia and the Great
Powers,the New Zealand scholar Nicholas Tarling(2010) states, “ASEANextended the idea
that, rather than seeking security from outside the region, its members could secure it by
agreement inside, perhaps more effectively.aepr_117522..38
Before ASEAN, there were two attempts to organize Southeast Asia. MAPHILINDO,
for Malaysia, the Philippines, and Indonesia, agreed upon in August 1963 to co-opt the
plan to form Malaysia out of Malaya, Singapore, North Borneo (Sabah), and Sarawak,
which Indonesia and the Philippines opposed, quickly broke apart (Tarling, 2010).
Meanwhile, in 1961,Malaya, the Philippines, and Thailand had set up the Association
of Southeast Asia (ASA), ostensibly for purposes of economic, social, cultural, educa-
tional, and other nonsecurity or nonpolitical cooperation. With ASEAN’s founding in
August 1967,ASA’s projects were turned over to the new association, which now included
Indonesia and Singapore as well as the three ASA members.
†Correspondence: Rodolfo C. Severino, Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, 30 Heng Mui Keng
Terrace,Singapore 119614. Email: severino@iseas.edu.sg
doi: 10.1111/j.1748-3131.2011.01175.x Asian Economic Policy Review (2011) 6, 22–38
© 2011 The Author
Asian Economic Policy Review © 2011 Japan Center for Economic Research
22
The projection of ASEAN initially as an economic, social, and cultural association,
rather than as one pursuing political and security purposes, was meant to dispel the
notion that it was a military alliance or, worse, a toolof American foreign policy. At their
first summit, in February 1976, the ASEAN leaders issued the Declaration of ASEAN
Concord, in which they laid down ASEAN’s objectives and principles in much greater
detail than their foreign ministers had done eight and a half years before. The Declaration,
later known as Bali Concord I (Bali Concord II was issued at another ASEAN summit
meeting in Bali, in 2003), included a Program of Action covering the political,economic,
social, and cultural and information areas.
At that 1976 summit in Bali, ASEAN set up a central secretariat. The fact that the
Secretary-General was severely circumscribed and held on a short leash does not detract
from the significance that the establishment of a central ASEAN Secretariat held for
Southeast Asian regionalism.
2. Economic Cooperation to the Fore
Finally, theASEAN leaders directed the ASEAN economic ministers (AEM) to convene in
Kuala Lumpur in March1976 to discuss specific measures for the establishment of “large-
scale” industrial projects and a system of preferential trading arrangements.
The Preferential Trading Arrangement (PTA) agreement covered“basic commodities,”
particularly food and energy, the products of the ASEAN Industrial Projects (AIP), and
the goods agreed upon in negotiations among the member states. The PTA essentially
provided for “margins of preference”below normal tariffs on covered goods. The number
of items listed, the margins of preference, and the cutoff import value were raised peri-
odically until the ASEAN PTA was effectively superseded by the 1992 agreement on the
Common Effective Preferential Tariffs for the ASEAN Free Trade Area (CEPT/AFTA).
One basic difference between CEPT/AFTA and the PTA is that, in the case of CEPT/
AFTA, everything is included unless excluded,w hereas, in the PTA’s case, everything was
excluded unless specifically included. Another is that the PTA provided for “margins of
preference” for intra-ASEAN trade, that is, percentage discounts from normal tariffs, so
that the PTA tariff would remain high if the base tariff were high to begin with. The
CEPT/AFTA, on the other hand,prescribes the lowering of actual intra-ASEAN tariffs in
tranches until their eventual elimination.
The other pillar of ASEAN economic cooperation was the AIP. At their March 1977
inaugural meeting, the AEM assigned a urea fertilizer plant each to Indonesia and Malay-
sia, superphosphates to the Philippines, diesel engines to Singapore, and soda ash to
Thailand. The Basic Agreement on the AIP, signed in March 1980, subjected to ASEAN
consultation the establishment of similar projects in other ASEAN countries. This attempt
at a regional industrial policy soon foundered on the refusal of ASEAN member states to
refrain from putting up industries competing with an AIP, the decisions by member states
to change the industries that had been assigned to them, and the lack of member states’
enthusiasm for projects other than their own. The member states also refused to commit
Rodolfo C. Severino Politics of Economic Cooperation
© 2011 The Author
Asian Economic Policy Review © 2011 Japan Center for Economic Research 23

To continue reading

Request your trial

VLEX uses login cookies to provide you with a better browsing experience. If you click on 'Accept' or continue browsing this site we consider that you accept our cookie policy. ACCEPT